ORDER NO. 96-021
ENTERED JAN 12 1996
THIS IS AN ELECTRONIC COPY
BEFORE THE PUBLIC UTILITY COMMISSION
OF OREGON
CP 1, CP 14, CP 15
In the Matter of the Application of
Electric Lightwave, Inc. for a Certificate of Authority
to Provide Telecommunications Services in Oregon. (CP 1)
In the Matter of the Application of MFS Intelenet of
Oregon, Inc. for a Certificate of Authority to Provide
Telecommunications Services in Oregon and Classification
as a Competitive Telecommunications Provider. (CP 14) In the Matter of the Application of MCI Metro Access Transmission Services, Inc. for a Certificate of Authority to Provide Telecommunications Services in Oregon and Classification as a Competitive Telecommunications Provider. (CP 15) |
) ) ) ) ) ORDER ) ) ) ) |
CONTESTED ISSUES
How will the application affect rates for local exchange telecommunications customers within and outside the competitive zone?
(a) What is the financial impact on LECs if the application is granted?
Commission Findings and Decision
How will the applications affect competition within the local exchange service area?
(a) Will the applicants' proposed service stimulate competition?
(b) How will local exchange providers respond to the presence of competitive local service providers?
Commission Findings and Decision
How will the application affect access by customers to high quality, innovative telecommunications service in the local exchange service area?
(a) What new or improved services will be offered by the applicants or the LECs?
(b) Will the applicants' application affect the quality of service offered by the LECs?
(c) What effect will the application have on economic efficiency?
Commission Findings and Decision
Other Considerations
(a) Should the Commission authorize the applicants to provide service within the entire area designated in the application?
(b) If the application is approved, under what circumstances may the applicants deny service to a potential customer within the competitive zone?
(c) Should the Commission impose requirements on the applicants in addition to those in OAR 860, Ch. 32?
(d) Should the applicants be subject to the Oregon CustomerAccess Plan?
(e) What ancillary services should the applicants be required to provide?
(1) How will the applicants supply such services?
(2) What ancillary (direct access) services, features, and functions should the LECs be required to make available the applicants?
(f) What intercompany compensation arrangements are needed for calls placed within an exchange and calls placed between exchanges within the competitive zone?
Summary of Positions
Reciprocal Usage-Sensitive Compensation
Opposing Arguments
Price Squeeze
Impact on Local Rates
Lack of Reciprocity
Measurement-Related Costs
Cost Causation
Traffic Patterns
Network Architecture
Interim Universal Service Charge
Opposing Arguments
Flat Rate Compensation
Opposing Arguments
One Way Compensation
Opposing Arguments
Bill and Keep Compensation
Opposing Arguments
Commission Findings and Decision
Issue IV:
(f)(1) What arrangements are necessary to accommodate existing extended area service (EAS) routes?
Commission Findings and Decision
(g) Is the applicants' proposed service compatible with the existing network configuration and other requirements associated with providing enhanced 911 service?
Commission Findings and Decision
(h) What interconnection arrangements between the applicants and LECs should be provided?
(1) What should be the conditions of such arrangements?
(2) What technical issues must be resolved?
Physical Interconnection Issues
Commission Findings and Decision
Unbundling and Resale Issues
Commission Findings and Decision
(i) What arrangements are necessary for the assignment of telephone numbers to the applicants?
Commission Findings and Decision
(j) What arrangements are necessary to ensure adequate number portability?
Database Number Portability
Interim Portability
Commission Findings and Decision
(k) If the applications are granted, should the Commission impose any limits on LEC pricing flexibility?
Commission Findings and Decision
Appendix A: The Applications
Appendix B: Parties' Representatives
Appendix C: Stipulation
Appendix D: Partial Stipulation
These applications were filed pursuant to ORS 759.050, which
authorizes the Commission to certify additional providers of
local exchange telecommunications services in the existing
service areas of telecommunications utilities if the proposed
service is in the public interest. In making this determination,
the Commission must consider the effect on rates for local
exchange telecommunications service customers both within and
outside the competitive zone; the effect on competition in the
local exchange telecommunications service area; the effect on
access by customers to high quality innovative telecommunications
service in the local exchange telecommunications service area;
and any other facts the Commission considers relevant.
The issues listed below reflect the factors that ORS 759.050 requires the Commission to consider. After considering these factors, the Commission finds that the applications of Electric Lightwave, Inc., MFS Intelenet of Oregon, Inc., and MCI Metro Access Telecommunications Services, Inc., for authority to provide local exchange service in the service territories of USWC and GTE are in the public interest and should be granted. Pursuant to this finding the following telephone exchanges are designated as competitive zones under the statute: Burlington, North Plains, Lake Oswego, Milwaukie-Oak Grove, Oregon City, and Portland (USWC exchanges); and Beaverton, Forest Grove, Gresham, Hillsboro, Scholls, Sherwood, Stafford, and Tigard (GTE exchanges).
Issue I: How will the application affect rates for local exchange telecommunications customers within and outside the competitive zone?
(a) What is the financial impact on LECs if the application
is granted?
In the long term, the Commission believes that competitive
entry will cause downward pressure on rates for the
telecommunications services, but the effect of the market
presence of the new entrants cannot be quantified at this time.
The Commission finds that competition will develop gradually, and
that the initial beneficiaries of competition will mainly be
business customers. Business rates will fall over time, but
because firms will compete in terms of service quality and
services offered as well as price, we cannot presently quantify
the potential drop in rates. If the LECs lose revenues to
competition within the competitive zone, there will be upward
pressure on residential rates outside the zone to offset the lost
revenues.
It is not certain, however, that local exchange competition
will cause the local exchange companies (LECs) to lose revenue.
They may lose market share to the new entrants, but the market is
likely to grow through an increase in consumption of lines and
services. Net revenue loss could also be contained through
cost-cutting and use of more efficient technologies.
The financial impact on the LECs will also depend on the
extent of market penetration by the alternative exchange carriers
(AECs) and their pattern of entry. It will also depend on the
LECs' response to competition and on the regulatory policies
adopted by the Commission.
II. How will the applications affect competition within the local exchange service area?
(a) Will the applicants' proposed service stimulate competition?
(b) How will local exchange providers respond to the
presence of competitive local service providers?
Competitive entry will increase the quality and variety of
service and decrease price for telecommunications customers.
Entry should also promote deployment of new technology and foster
innovation. Over time, benefits from new technology and
innovation will flow to all users. In the short term, the main
beneficiaries are likely to be business customers.
The development of competition depends on appropriate
conditions being established by the Commission. These conditions
include elimination of entry restrictions, equal access to rights
of way, local number portability, dialing parity, unbundling the
monopoly local exchange network, comprehensive interconnection,
cost-based pricing by the incumbents, imputation, elimination of
resale restrictions, and open technical standards. These issues
must be resolved as we move forward into a competitive
environment.
The incumbent local exchange providers will respond to
competition by lowering prices, increasing efficiency, and
creating new service packages. In the longer term, they are likely
to respond by improving the quality of their service.
III. How will the application affect access by customers to high quality, innovative telecommunications service in the local exchange service area?
(a) What new or improved services will be offered by the applicants or the LECs?
(b) Will the applicants' application affect the quality of service offered by the LECs?
(c) What effect will the application have on economic
efficiency?
The applicants' initial service offerings will be similar to
those already available. Incumbents and new entrants will also
compete on the basis of customer service. At the very least,
competition will improve the quality of service and enhance the
economic efficiency of participants in the local exchange market.
In the long term, the competitive environment should promote new
products, innovation, and the deployment of existing technologies
not yet in widespread use.
IV. Other Considerations
(a) Should the Commission authorize the applicants to
provide service within the entire area designated in the
application?
In accordance with the parties' stipulation, the Commission
authorizes the applicants in all three dockets to provide service
within the entire geographic areas designated in their respective
applications.
(b) If the application is approved, under what
circumstances may the applicants deny service to a potential
customer within the competitive zone?
It is unnecessary to regulate the conditions under which the
entrants may deny service to potential customers. It would be
unreasonable to require that new entrants serve all customers,
business and residential, within a given geographic area until
such time as their networks are in place. Once their networks are
developed, the AECs should have no incentive to refuse service to
any customer. If denial of service by AECs creates a problem in
the future, the Commission has statutory authority to impose
conditions on the AECs and could impose conditions similar to
those under which the LECs operate.
(c) Should the Commission impose requirements on the
applicants in addition to those in OAR 860, Chapter 32?
Consumer protection measures are critical when captive rate
payers are forced to use monopoly service providers. The presence
of alternatives helps protect consumer interests. Requirements in
addition to those in OAR 860, Chapter 32 are thus unnecessary at
this time. Once competition is established, we will consider
whether consumer protection requirements imposed on LECs should
be relaxed.
(d) Should the applicants be subject to the Oregon Customer Access Plan?
(1) If so, what conditions or procedures are necessary to
facilitate compliance with the Plan?
Under the Partial Stipulation, the applicants will contribute
to the Oregon Customer Access Fund. AECs will also have to comply
with the 1994 Oregon Customer Access Plan, Parts V.D, VI.C, IX.D,
and XI.F. AECs should not participate in pooling arrangements.
(e) What ancillary services should the applicants be required to provide?
(1) How will the applicants supply such services?
(2): What ancillary services, features, and functions
should the LECs be required to make available to the applicants?
The only ancillary service the AECs must provide is E-911 service. Public health and safety concerns justify that requirement. We expect, however, that the AECs will also offer other ancillary services because their customers will demand them. We prefer to let the market dictate what services AECs offer. Applicants will supply ancillary services with their own equipment or through arrangements with the LECs.
The Commission can consider on a case by case basis relaxing
the consumer protection and service requirements imposed on the
LECs. Until competition has become established, however, we will
not consider lifting the ancillary service requirements on the
LECs.
Issue IV(e)(2) was resolved by stipulation. The LECs agree to
treat the AECs as they treat independent local exchange carriers
(ILECs) for purposes of making ancillary services available. The
resolution of this issue is consistent with our decision that
AECs should have co-carrier status with other local exchange
service providers. Throughout this order, we have mandated
treatment for the AECs that is analogous to the treatment the
ILECs receive from the LECs.
(f) What intercompany compensation arrangements are needed
for calls placed within an exchange and calls placed between
exchanges within the competitive zone?
The Commission finds that compensation arrangements for the
exchange of local and Extended Area Service (EAS) traffic should
be based on bill and keep arrangements for an period of not more
than 24 months. We are persuaded that bill and keep has fewer
shortcomings than other compensation proposals in this case and
will function as a reasonable compensation mechanism during the
initial stages of competitive entry into the local exchange
market. At the same time, we recognize that bill and keep is only
a temporary means of accommodating local exchange competition and
that a more permanent intercarrier compensation mechanism must be
developed as competition progresses.
We order a work group to study intercompany compensation
issues and to formulate proposals for implementing a reciprocal
interconnection rate structure applicable to all switched
telecommunications traffic. The interconnection compensation work
group shall consist of representatives from USWC, GTE, Staff,
MFS, ELI, MCImetro, and other interested parties, including
consumer groups, ILECs, IXCs, and other competitive providers.
Staff shall submit a report to the Commission every six months
detailing the progress of the work group. In addition,
applicants, USWC and GTE shall conduct and submit traffic studies
of local and EAS traffic exchanged with other carriers. The first
study shall be submitted within six months from the date of this
order. Additional traffic studies shall be submitted every six
months thereafter. This information can be used by the work group
to develop its recommendations regarding reciprocal compensation
arrangements for terminating traffic.
(1) What arrangements are necessary to accommodate existing
Extended Area Service routes?
Because we have decided to adopt bill and keep as the form of
intercompany compensation for local traffic, it would create an
anomaly to impose a different form of compensation on the AECs
within the EAS region. Also, there is no cost justification for
treating incumbent LECs and AECs differently for EAS purposes.
Current EAS routes are established based on criteria that
consider community calling areas of interest. In the case of
AECs, calls between exchanges reflect end users' calling areas of
interest between two neighboring exchanges just as if calls were
handled by the incumbent LECs. The identity of the companies
involved is irrelevant. The proposal to treat LECs and AECs
differently within the EAS region would severely disadvantage the
new entrants and hamper competition.
Until otherwise ordered by the Commission, existing local
exchange boundaries and EAS routes shall apply to AECs as well as
incumbents for the purpose of distinguishing between local and
toll calling and for intercompany compensation. Thus, traffic
originated by any authorized local carrier that crosses exchange
boundaries within the Portland EAS region shall be treated as a
local call and compensated on a bill and keep basis.
(g) Is the applicants' proposed service compatible with the existing network configuration and other requirements associated with providing enhanced 911
(E-911) service?
The AECs' proposed service will be compatible with the existing network configuration and other requirements associated with providing E-911 service. The AECs have primary responsibility to work with the E-911 agencies to make certain that all users of their services have access to the emergency system.(h) What interconnection arrangements between the applicants and the LECs should be provided?
(1) What should be the conditions of such arrangements?
(2) What technical issues must be resolved?
Physical interconnection. The Commission finds that the
applicants should be permitted to interconnect with incumbent
providers on the same terms and conditions that LECs have used to
interconnect their telecommunications networks. This process
contemplates that the interconnecting parties will negotiate
mutually acceptable locations where network facilities can be
joined. We find that the parties will bargain on more equal terms
and have a greater incentive to agree upon the most efficient
interconnection if all costs associated with the construction of
facilities are shared equally.
The Commission declines to adopt recommendations that would give either the LECs or the AECs the power to unilaterally designate interconnection meet points. In a competitive environment, carriers should not have an opportunity to select interconnection locations that may disadvantage competing providers. The applicants shall not take any action that impairs the ability of the incumbent LECs to meet the service standards specified by the Commission.
Where parties are unable to agree on mutually acceptable
interconnection arrangements, the Commission should be notified
within three days so the dispute can be resolved on an expedited
basis.
The applicants have indicated that they intend to abide by
existing protocols and procedures and install equipment that
complies with network standards. We therefore have no reason to
believe that technical problems will occur.
Unbundling and Resale. These issues will be addressed
in docket UM 351. An order is expected shortly in that docket.
(i) What arrangements are necessary for the assignment of
telephone numbers to the applicants?
The AECs cannot compete in the local exchange market unless they have nondiscriminatory access to telephone number. Competitive entrants are entitled to receive central office code assignments according to the same rates, terms, and conditions as any LEC. Guidelines for the assignment of numbers are in place. USWC, as the Numbering Plan Administrator, shall apply these guidelines in a nondiscriminatory manner.
(j) What arrangements are necessary to ensure adequate
number portability?
Number portability is essential to the development of
effective local exchange competition. It is therefore important
for the telecommunications industry to produce a database
solution as soon as possible. At the same time, the Commission
does not want to duplicate efforts now underway to arrive at a
national solution to portability issues. A work group is
established to monitor developments in this area, including the
results of database number portability trials in other states.
The work group shall submit periodic reports evaluating the
progress of database portability trials and include
recommendations regarding the timing and implementation of a
database number portability solution. The first report shall be
filed with the Commission no later than July 1, 1996.
Interim number portability shall be offered by allowing AECs
to use remote call forwarding or directory number route indexing
technology. The evidence indicates that these methods have
technical limitations, but there appears to be general agreement
that they will function reasonably well as an interim solution.
USWC and GTE shall file tariffs within 30 days from the date of
this order offering both the remote call forwarding and directory
number route indexing functions at a price equal to total service
long run incremental cost. The tariffs may include a nonrecurring
service provisioning charge, which should also be set at cost.
(k) If the application is granted, should the Commission impose any limits on LEC pricing flexibility?
LECs should be afforded pricing flexibility under ORS 759.050(5) once (a) the applicants have received certificates of authority to provide local exchange service consistent with the terms of this order; (b) the Commission approves the tariffs filed by USWC and GTE in compliance with this order; and (c) USWC and GTE certify that interconnection arrangements are in place and a mutual exchange of traffic exists with an authorized AEC. These conditions will ensure that a competitive alternative is present at the time LECs receive the pricing flexibility contemplated by ORS 759.050. We also find that the pricing flexibility authorized in USWC's Alternative Form of Regulation plan should not be restricted in this proceeding.
ORDER NO.
ENTERED
BEFORE THE PUBLIC UTILITY COMMISSION
OF OREGON
CP 1, CP 14, CP 15
In the Matter of the Application of
Electric Lightwave, Inc. for a Certificate of Authority
to Provide Telecommunications Services in Oregon. (CP 1)
In the Matter of the Application of MFS Intelenet of
Oregon, Inc. for a Certificate of Authority to Provide
Telecommunications Services in Oregon and Classification
as a Competitive Telecommunications Provider. (CP 14) In the Matter of the Application of MCI Metro Access Transmission Services, Inc. for a Certificate of Authority to Provide Telecommunications Services in Oregon and Classification as a Competitive Telecommunications Provider. (CP 15) |
) ) ) ) ) ORDER ) ) ) ) |
DISPOSITION: APPLICATIONS
GRANTED
The Applications (BACK)
Docket CP 1: Electric Lightwave, Inc. On November 14, 1994, Electric Lightwave, Inc. (ELI) filed an application with the Commission for certification to provide telecommunications service in Oregon as a competitive provider. ELI seeks authority to provide intraexchange switched service in areas coextensive with the Lake Oswego, Milwaukie, Oak Grove, Oregon City, and Portland local exchanges of
U S WEST Communications, Inc. (USWC), and the Beaverton,
Gresham, Hillsboro, Sherwood, Stafford, and Tigard local
exchanges of GTE Northwest, Incorporated. (GTE).
Docket CP 14: MFS Intelenet of Oregon, Inc. On December
14, 1994, MFS Intelenet of Oregon, Inc. (MFS), filed an
application with the Commission for certification to provide
telecommunications service in Oregon as a competitive provider.
MFS seeks authority to provide intraexchange switched services in
areas coextensive with the Burlington, Lake Oswego, Milwaukie,
North Plains, Oak Grove, Oregon City, and Portland (local
exchanges of USWC, and the Beaverton, Forest Grove, Gresham,
Hillsboro, Scholls, Sherwood, Stafford, and Tigard local
exchanges of GTE.
Docket CP 15: MCI Metro Access Transmission Services, Inc.
On December 20, 1994, MCImetro Access Transmission Services, Inc.
(MCImetro) applied for authority to provide telecommunications
service in Oregon as a competitive provider. MCImetro seeks to
provide intraexchange switched telecommunications services in the
Portland metropolitan area, including portions of Multnomah,
Clackamas, and Washington counties. Service will be provided in
areas coextensive with the Lake Oswego, Milwaukie, Oak Grove,
Oregon City, Portland exchanges of USWC, and the Beaverton,
Forest Grove, Gresham, Hillsboro, Scholls, Sherwood, and Stafford
local exchanges of GTE.
The applications are described more fully in Appendix A.
On January 26, 1995, dockets CP 1, CP 14, and CP 15 were
consolidated for purposes of hearing and decision. Protests to
the applications were filed by USWC, GTE, Oregon Cable
Telecommunications Association (OCTA), Oregon Exchange Carriers
Association (OECA), Oregon Independent Telephone Association
(OITA), PTI Communications Inc. (PTI), Teleport Communications
Group, Inc. (TCG), and Mr. R. Rose. Petitions to intervene were
filed by AT&T Communications of the Pacific Northwest, Inc.
(AT&T), McCaw Cellular Communications, Inc. (McCaw), MCI
Telecommunications Corporation (MCI), Sprint Communications
Company L.P. (Sprint), United Telephone Company of the Northwest
(United), OCTA, and PTI. The Citizens' Utility Board (CUB) filed
a notice of intervention. All petitions to intervene were
granted.
On July 10-15, 1995, an evidentiary hearing was held in these
matters in Salem, Oregon, before Samuel J. Petrillo and Ruth
Crowley, Administrative Law Judges. Appearances were entered on
behalf of ELI, MFS, MCImetro, GTE, USWC, AT&T, OCTA, OECA,
OITA, Sprint, TCG, and the Commission Staff. Party
representatives are listed in Appendix B.
On August 18, 1995, the parties submitted simultaneous briefs
and the record was closed.
The telecommunications policy goals established by the Oregon
Legislature and administered by the Commission are found in ORS
759.015. That statute provides:
The Legislative Assembly finds and declares that it is the
goal of the State of Oregon to secure and maintain high-quality
universal telecommunications service at just and reasonable rates
for all classes of customers and to encourage innovation within
the industry by a balanced program of regulation and competition.
The commission shall administer the statutes with respect to
telecommunications rates and services in accordance with this
policy.
These applications to provide local exchange
telecommunications services are filed pursuant to ORS 759.050,
the "competitive zone law." Under ORS 759.050(2)(a),
the Commission may:
certify one or more persons, including another
telecommunications utility, to provide local exchange
telecommunications service within the local exchange
telecommunications service area of a certified telecommunications
utility, if the commission determines that such authorization
would be in the public interest. For the purpose of determining
whether such authorization would be in the public interest, the
commission shall consider:
(A) The effect on rates for local exchange telecommunications
service customers both within and outside the competitive zone.
(B) The effect on competition in the local exchange
telecommunications service area.
(C) The effect on access by customers to high quality
innovative tele-communications service in the local exchange
telecommunications service area.
(D) Any other facts the commission considers relevant.
Under ORS 759.050(2)(c), the Commission may establish
reasonable conditions or restrictions on the certificates of
telecommunications providers to provide local exchange service.
Conditions may be imposed by the Commission at the time of
issuance or thereafter.
The parties in these proceedings engaged in a number of settlement conferences, which resulted in the submission of a Stipulation and a Partial Stipulation. These documents are attached to this order as Appendices C and D.
The Stipulation addresses Issue IV(e)(2), regarding
ancillary services, features, and functions that the local
exchange carriers (LECs) should be required to make available to
the applicants. Under the terms of this document, GTE and USWC
agree to offer a number of ancillary services to the applicants
on a nondiscriminatory basis and on the same terms and
conditions, other than price, that are offered to other LECs in
Oregon:
In addition to the above, the Stipulation provides that GTE
will offer the applicants and their customers with Yellow Pages
advertising, basic Yellow Pages listings, White Pages information
listings, and directory distribution in GTE directories on a
nondiscriminatory basis and on the same terms and conditions,
other than price, as it offers to other LECs in Oregon.
The Stipulation also provides that the applicants may request Commission relief to obtain ancillary services not listed above, and that USWC and GTE may oppose such requests. The signatories to the Stipulation are AT&T, ELI, GTE, MFS, OCTA, OECA, Sprint, TCG, and USWC. OITA does not oppose the Stipulation.
The Partial Stipulation is separated into five
different Items, each of which has been agreed to by different
parties.
Item 1 of the Partial Stipulation is an agreement that
it is in the public interest to grant the applications and to
designate the exchanges listed in the applications as competitive
zones. The signatories are ELI, MFS, AT&T, Sprint, TCG, OCTA,
and OECA. OITA and USWC are not opposed.
Item 2 addresses Issue IV(a). ELI, MFS, AT&T,
Sprint, TCG, OCTA, OECA, GTE and USWC agree that the applicants
in all three dockets should be authorized to provide service
within the entire geographic areas designated in their respective
applications. They also agree that the Commission should
acknowledge the concerns of USWC and GTE that LECs and
alternative exchange carriers (AECs) do not have an equal
obligation to serve customers. OITA is not opposed.
Item 3 deals with Issue IV(d). It first provides that
ELI, MFS, and the LECs will terminate all intrastate traffic
originating on one another's network. The signatories to this
agreement are ELI, MFS, AT&T, Sprint, TCG, OCTA, GTE, and
USWC. OITA and OECA are unopposed.
In addition, ELI, MFS, AT&T, Sprint, TCG, OECA, GTE, USWC agree to contribute to the Oregon Customer Access Fund (OCAF) and to comply with specific provisions of the Oregon Customer Access Plan (OCAP). Where an AEC terminates long distance traffic directly or indirectly from interexchange carriers (IXCs) or from its own toll network to its own end office and end user customers, the AEC will charge an OCAF and Oregon Universal Service Fund (OUSF) rate element, in addition to switched access charges, on all intrastate terminating carrier common line access minutes or their equivalent. The revenues collected from the OCAF and OUSF charges paid by AECs will be turned over to OECA for OCAF pool distribution. The agreement is intended to coincide with Order No. 93-1133, which funds OCAF and OUSF by a cents per minute charge on all intrastate terminating rated CCL switched access minutes.
The signatories indicated above also agree that the AECs, as
contributors to OCAF, shall comply with OECA's informational and
operational needs. Specifically, the AECs will comply with Parts
V.D, VI.C, IX.D, and XI.F of the 1994 OCAP. AECs will not
participate in the OCAF/OUSF pooling arrangements because of the
extensive regulatory oversight that would be required.
Item 4 of the partial stipulation deals with Issue
IV(j). ELI, MFS, AT&T, Sprint, OCTA, TCG, OECA, and GTE
propose that the Commission open a docket no later than January
31, 1996, to consider and resolve the issue of permanent number
portability. In the meantime, the applicants, OECA, USWC, and GTE
and other interested parties shall develop a work group to
evaluate the results of number portability trials in other
states. OITA is not opposed to this agreement.
Item 5 was signed by ELI, MFS, Sprint, AT&T, OCTA,
TCG, GTE, and USWC. These parties recommend that the following
issues should be addressed in other Commission dockets:
Disposition of
Stipulations (BACK)
The Commission has reviewed the stipulations in light of the
record in this case. We adopt the Stipulation in its entirety.
That agreement resolves Issue IV(e)(2) regarding the ancillary
services the LECs will offer to the AECs.
The Commission also adopts Items 2, 3, and 5 of the Partial Stipulation, thereby resolving Issue IV(a) relating to the geographic scope of the applications, and Issue IV(d) relating to OCAF/OCAP issues. We do not adopt Item 1 because it relates to the public interest determination required by ORS 759.050(2)(a), and must be decided based on the record in this case. We adopt Item 4 in part. Specifically, we mandate establishment of a work group on permanent number portability, but decline to open a docket on that issue at present. Number portability is discussed at Issue IV(j) below.
CONTESTED ISSUES
How will the application affect rates for local exchange telecommunications customers within and outside the competitive zone?
(a) What is the financial impact on LECs if the application
is granted?
Positions of the Parties
Staff states that the AECs' entry will cause downward
pressure on rates for the telecommunications services they offer,
particularly to business customers. Staff argues that prices are
also likely to decline as competition motivates the applicants
and the incumbent LECs to develop more efficient, less costly
methods of supplying telecommunications services. Staff argues
that competition may also cause the LECs to seek rate rebalancing
within and outside the competitive zones to bring rates more in
line with the underlying economic costs of providing
telecommunications services. A possible consequence of
rebalancing is higher rates for high cost, rural service areas
and for residential services generally.
If the applications are granted, Staff maintains that the LECs will lose customers and revenue. The extent of these losses in the Portland metropolitan area depends on a number of factors, including AEC market penetration; the expansion of telecommunications service markets as a result of competition and additional demand caused by price reductions; LEC cost savings from not serving customers lost to AECs; and terms and conditions established by the Commission for local competition
(Issues IV a-k).
Staff acknowledges the arguments of the applicants and others,
that potential LEC revenue losses may be offset by new revenues
from expanded telecommunications services markets. However, Staff
notes that no party provided a quantitative analysis of the
potential financial impacts of market stimulation due to new
entrants.
Regarding market stimulation due to reduced prices, Staff
challenges comparisons between local exchange competition and
competition in the interLATA toll market, where price reductions
stimulated the market for long distance services. Staff argues
that the local exchange and long distance markets are
fundamentally different. Many of the price reductions in the
interLATA toll markets resulted not from competition, but from
regulatory decisions to shift LECs costs from toll and access
services to local exchange services. Thus, the cost of access
declined for IXCs.
Staff also maintains that market demand for local exchange
services is less price elastic than demand for toll services.
Estimates of price elasticity of demand for local exchange
services are about -.05 to -.10. That is, a 10 percent decrease
in price would increase market demand by only .5 to 1.0 percent.
Toll, on the other hand, has a price elasticity in the range of
-.36 to -.58; a 10 percent decrease in price would stimulate
market demand by 3.6 to 5.8 percent. Finally, toll services are
sold on a measured usage basis, whereas most local exchange
service is sold on a flat rate basis. Thus, greater usage will
increase IXC revenues but not LEC revenues from flat rate
service. LEC revenues are increased by stimulating demand for
more access lines.
To the extent that the LECs lose customers to the AECs, they
may avoid certain costs associated with serving those customers.
Staff argues that any potential cost savings due to the LECs'
serving fewer customers would be consumed by increased
advertising and marketing expenses and potential increases in
depreciation expenses as LECs attempt to adjust to a more
competitive environment.
Using ELI and MFS forecasts of local exchange customer and
revenue growth in the Portland area in the next several years,
Staff projected the AECs' penetration of the Portland
metropolitan area business market. Based on these forecasts,
Staff concluded that there is a reasonable possibility that the
three applicants could attain a 20 percent penetration rate in
that market by the year 2001.
Staff performed quantitative analyses to estimate the possible
financial impacts of local competition on LEC revenues if the
applications are granted. Staff assumed that the AECs would
attain either a 10 percent or 20 percent share of the business
market in the Portland metropolitan area by 2001. Staff believes
that the 10 percent estimate is conservative.
For each of these scenarios Staff developed a mild and a
severe case. In the mild case, for USWC, Staff assumed that:
In the Staff's severe case, USWC is forced to reduce business
rates in the competitive zones to total service long run
incremental cost (TSLRIC). The table below shows USWC's revenue
erosion per year and residential rate increase per month for the
mild and severe case of each of Staff's scenarios:
USWC
Market Penetration | Case | Revenue Erosion (M/Yr.) |
Residential Rate Increase/Mo. |
10 percent | mild | $15.8 | $1.23 |
10 percent | severe | $50.2 | $3.92 |
20 percent | mild | $25.4 | $1.98 |
20 percent | severe | $56.1 | $4.39 |
Staff performed the same analyses for GTE, assuming loss of
revenues from basic local exchange service and EAS, plus $27.30
per month in vertical service and ancillary revenues (toll,
carrier access, miscellaneous) for each business line lost and
$15.69 per month in revenues for each residence line lost. Staff
made the same assumptions for GTE's severe case as it did for
USWC. The following table shows Staff's projected revenue erosion
and residential rate increase for GTE:
GTE
Market Penetration | Case | Revenue Erosion (M/Yr.) |
Residential Rate Increase/Mo. |
10 percent | mild | $11.5 | $2.49 |
10 percent | severe | $36.4 | $7.90 |
20 percent | mild | $18.6 | $4.03 |
20 percent | severe | $40.8 | $8.87 |
Staff believes that granting the applications carries the risk
of significant adverse impacts on GTE and USWC. The projected
revenue erosion could cause the LECs to seek rate rebalancing
within and outside the competitive zones. Such rebalancing could
erode internal LEC revenue support for higher cost service areas
and for residential services generally. Revenues available for
sharing under USWC's existing Alternative Form of Regulation
(AFOR) plan could also decline.
USWC agrees with Staff. USWC emphasizes that the AECs
will enter the urban business market, where services are
overpriced relative to cost. Historically, regulatory pricing has
kept business service rates, toll, and access charges much higher
than residential rates. Competitive entry will force business
rates down in the competitive zones and cause realignment of
prices outside the zones, with significant impact on residential
customers. Customers without a choice of carriers will be
responsible for covering costs and making up for competitive
losses as the incumbents' market share declines. Averaged rates,
one of the traditional support mechanisms for affordable
universal service, will come under severe pressure due to local
exchange competition.
USWC foresees a significant financial impact on the LECs if
the applications are granted, because the applicants will target
those parts of USWC's market where revenues are most greatly
concentrated. USWC prepared a confidential revenue impact
analysis based on Staff's market penetration figures, using the
same assumptions as Staff used, including the mild and severe
cases. USWC anticipates that the AECs' market penetration will be
even greater than Staff predicts, and that revenue losses will be
even more severe. USWC bases its conclusion in part on its own
experience in the United Kingdom. USWC witness Inouye also
testified that USWC had experienced a downward trend in its
market share for private line and special access services in the
competitive areas of Denver, Minneapolis, Seattle, and Portland.
GTE argues that the effect of competition on rates and
LEC revenues will remain unknown until the Commission decides how
GTE and USWC may price their services in docket UM 351. The
effect of competition on rates and the LECs will also depend on
which services the applicants offer and how those services are
priced. It is reasonable to assume that prices within the
competitive zones will eventually decline and that prices outside
the zones will increase.
According to GTE, the financial impact of competitive entry on
the LECs also depends on whether GTE and USWC are permitted to
rebalance their rates in response to competition. In the main,
however, GTE believes that Staff's analysis presents a reasonable
estimate of the magnitude of the impact of competition. Such an
impact could materially affect residential service rates within
and outside the zones and rates in general outside the
competitive zones. GTE also asserts that rate restructuring costs
will be incurred in order to gain the benefits of a more
competitive market.
Applicants argue that local exchange customers are
likely to see rate reductions and other benefits as a result of
competitive entry. The applicants believe that the market for
telecommunications services will expand with entry, and that loss
of market share does not necessarily mean revenue loss for the
incumbents.
The applicants argue that development of competition has been
slow in other jurisdictions where alternative carriers are
authorized to provide service and intercarrier arrangements are
directed by the regulatory agency. The applicants maintain that
incremental growth is the most likely scenario in Oregon as well.
Even when it is relatively easy for consumers to change
providers, as in the long distance market, experience has shown
that change comes slowly. Moreover, networks take time to
construct. Applicants note that it will also take time for the
Commission to create the conditions for effective competition
through costing, imputation, interconnection, unbundling, resale,
number portability, collocation, and universal service policies.
The applicants contend that there is no basis to grant the
incumbent LECs any immediate form of regulatory parity, such as
rate rebalancing. The applicants state that AEC entry into the
local exchange market will have little financial impact on the
incumbent LECs and will not have a negative effect on residential
rates within or outside the competitive zones. The applicants
also contend that competition will cause the local exchange
market to expand. Therefore, a decline in LEC market share does
not necessarily mean a decline in LEC revenues or profits.
The applicants further contend that Staff estimates of market
penetration and LEC financial impact are highly speculative and
based on untested assumptions. Staff's market penetration figures
are based on five year projections submitted by ELI and MFS, but
Staff did not review the assumptions underlying these
projections, such as the nature of intercompany compensation
arrangements or the availability of unbundled loops or number
portability. The applicants point out that Staff did not test its
market penetration projections against the experience in other
markets, such as the United Kingdom, New York, or Michigan, where
local exchange competition has been introduced. Further, Staff
did not compare its projections with experience in other market
segments that have been opened to competition, such as long
distance and competitive access provider services.
In addition, the applicants assert that there are other flaws
in the Staff analysis. Staff assumes that 100 percent of local
exchange market belongs to the incumbent LEC, so any revenues the
applicants gain is necessarily the incumbents' loss. The
applicants also argue that Staff did not take into account the
potential market stimulation effect on access line growth and did
not deal with offsetting factors like potential cost savings and
efficiencies realized by the incumbents. Finally, Staff did not
include the revenue that incumbents would receive from unbundled
network access channels if they were provided by LECs to AECs.
The applicants also challenge USWC's reliance on market
penetration data from the United Kingdom to support the claim
that AEC entry will have serious financial consequences for the
LECs. According to the applicants, the record is silent on the
market conditions in the United Kingdom at the time of the study.
For instance, it is not known whether basic telecommunications
service was bundled with cable service, or whether service was
priced on a usage basis. The level of market penetration for
basic service prior to competition is also unknown. Moreover, the
United Kingdom data is limited to the percentage of homes that
the USWC affiliate had marketed to; the overall market was much
larger. The applicants point out that, after 5 years, overall
market penetration was only 5 percent.
The applicants state that, even if the market penetration estimates made by Staff and USWC are accepted, the projected revenue impact of a 10 to 20 percent penetration, based on USWC's figures, is only 2.3 to 3.4 percent of USWC's Oregon revenue. The applicants argue that this level of revenue impact is insignificant.
OCTA and Sprint are aligned with the applicants.
AT&T notes that competition will drive prices to
incremental cost over time. Telecommunications customers
throughout the state should eventually benefit, but competition
will develop gradually. AT&T states that its experience with
long distance competition will not be repeated at the local
level. In the long distance market, AT&T's facilities could
be efficiently duplicated by new entrants, all AT&T services
were available for resale, and AT&T owned no bottleneck
facilities that competitors needed to provide service. Those
conditions are not present in the local exchange market.
AT&T points out that competition in the long distance
market has increased its revenues despite lower prices and vastly
decreased market share. AT&T argues that the LECs should
experience similar circumstances. The LECs have greater pricing
flexibility than AT&T had until 1988. Loss of market share
may not mean significant revenue loss because the market is
expanding. Moreover, competitive shifts should be gradual, so the
Commission can monitor and take appropriate remedial action.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue I
Competition in the switched local exchange market is new and
untested. Few jurisdictions have paved the way for competition;
even fewer have seen competition take hold. There is insufficient
experience elsewhere to allow us to draw conclusions about the
course of development in our own state. Even the parties admit
that market penetration and revenue loss figures are speculative.
There are far too many unknowns in this area to predict the
future.
We acknowledge that the LECs may lose market share and,
possibly, revenues as well. That could result in a rate increase
for residential customers. Overall, however, we are convinced of
the benefits of competition: increased customer choice, provider
diversity, improved service quality and technical and service
innovations. We therefore conclude that the benefit from granting
the applications outweighs the potential detriments.
Effect on Rates. We do not believe that
it is possible at present to quantify the effect of entry by the
AECs on rates inside or outside the zone. We are convinced of two
facts regarding the effect of competition on rates, however.
First, the AECs will not make major inroads into LEC revenues
overnight; they will develop their networks only gradually.
Development of AEC networks depends on a number of factors that
have yet to be determined, most critically the availability and
price of unbundled loop elements. These issues will be addressed
in docket UM 351. Even after the UM 351 order is entered, it will
take time to negotiate interconnection agreements.
Second, business customers are the most likely to benefit from
competition in the short term because the applicants will target
those customers first. Business rates will likely decline, but we
cannot quantify the level of decline at this point. We do not
know how the LECs will price their services in response to
initial competition or as a result of decisions in UM 351. Nor do
we know how the applicants will price their services. Aside from
price competition, carriers will also compete on the basis of
service quality and product offerings.
Over the long term, if the conditions for effective
competition are met, competition will drive prices closer to
incremental cost. Since business services are priced well above
cost, those rates should fall considerably. If the AECs also
target residential customers, those rates will fall within the
competitive zones as well. Because residential rates are priced
closer to cost, however, competition for residential customers
will develop more slowly than competition for business customers.
Competition is unlikely to reduce residential rates significantly
in the short term.
USWC, GTE, and Staff foresee a possible rebalancing of LEC
rates within and outside the competitive zones due to lost LEC
revenues. If the LECs lose revenues due to competition in the
zones, there will be upward pressure on residential rates to
offset the lost revenues. The need for rate rebalancing will
depend on a variety of factors including the extent of market
penetration by the AECs and their pattern of entry. It will also
depend on the unbundling, interconnection, pricing, number
portability, and access rules adopted here and in UM 351, as well
as LEC responses to competitive initiatives.
Staff attempted to quantify the impact on residential rates
for USWC and GTE, but did not assume any growth in the local
telecommunications service market. We are not persuaded that the
market for new lines will be price inelastic. The
telecommunications market is changing in ways that cannot be
predicted. In the developing environment, new technology may
create unforeseen demand for new lines. We also agree with
MCImetro that businesses will use more lines if the price for
access lines fell more than in Staff's analysis. Even without
taking into account potential new services developed and offered
by entrants, businesses might well switch from PBX to Centrex, or
might add fax lines or dedicated computer modem lines. Moreover,
reduced prices and competition in terms of service quality could
well induce businesses to protect their information flows with
redundant lines. Market growth could mitigate any LEC revenue
loss due to competition and relieve the upward pressure on rates
outside the zones.
Competition for high profit customers may cost the LECs some
of the revenue that, as USWC claims, currently subsidizes service
to less profitable residential customers. Although the LECs have
an obligation to provide universal service, we have decided, in
docket UM 731, that the AECs should also contribute to universal
service support. Universal service issues are also addressed
below under Issue IV(f).
Financial Impact on the LECs. It is
probable that the AECs will, over time, capture a significant
percentage of the local exchange market. The parties differ
greatly in their estimates of AEC market penetration, however.
Staff estimates a 10 to 20 percent penetration of the business
market in the competitive zones by 2001. USWC argues that
penetration will be on the high end of Staff's projections, with
the greatest penetration in private line and special access
services. These projections do not consider the possibility of a
growing market for local exchange services. If competition
stimulates the market, as we consider likely, the LECs could lose
market share without losing revenues, similar to AT&T's
experience in the long distance market.
Staff's projections do not consider the experience of
competitors in other jurisdictions. In Washington State, for
instance, new entrant market share is nearly zero. ELI and TCG
Seattle have filed contracts with the Washington Commission to
provide local exchange service to a total of 386 lines. In New
York City, where local competition has been in operation for the
longest period of time, the highest reported nonBell competitor's
share of access traffic is only 3 percent.
It is difficult to extrapolate from these data with any
certainty. As noted, we are looking at a small number of
jurisdictions. Moreover, we know little about the conditions
unique to each area. In the United Kingdom study, for example,
the applicants have pointed out many areas of uncertainty that
prevent us from drawing any definite conclusions about how local
exchange competition will develop in Oregon. Finally, we cannot
reliably compare figures on the share of access traffic, which
are usage based, with Staff's figures on market penetration,
which are expressed in terms of customers (who may have many
lines) or with the Washington data, which is based on number of
access lines.
Before AEC market share is able to increase substantially, the
AECs and LECs must negotiate interconnection agreements, the AECs
must construct the parts of their network that they do not
purchase or lease from the LECs, and the Commission must resolve
outstanding issues relating to competition. These things will all
take time. Even if the applicants garner the market share
predicted by Staff, USWC will experience a revenue loss equal to
2.3 to 3.4 percent of its Oregon revenues, without taking into
account market growth or avoided costs.
USWC witness Inouye argued that USWC experienced a downward
trend in its market share for private line and special access
services in the competitive areas of Denver, Minneapolis,
Seattle, and Portland. That claim is part of USWC's argument that
it will suffer serious revenue consequences from competitive
entry. We have information to the contrary. We take official
notice of an exhibit entered into evidence in UM 351, AT&T
Confidential Exhibit 9. Because the exhibit is confidential, we
will disclose no specific figures. That exhibit demonstrates that
USWC is losing market share to competitors in the high capacity
telecommunications market in Portland, but that its revenues in
that market are increasing due to overall market growth. Thus,
the exhibit refutes USWC's claim that decline in market share
necessarily entails revenue loss.
In view of these facts, we conclude that AEC entry into the
local exchange market will not have a significant impact on the
LECs in the near term. If competitive entry does significantly
affect LEC revenue, the LECs may seek rate relief from the
Commission, including interim relief. USWC may seek to have its
AFOR plan modified if its equity return falls below the minimum
level prescribed in the plan. Finally, the Commission may
rebalance LEC rates or take other appropriate action if
warranted.
Aside from the revenue impacts associated with competitive
entry, the LECs also face the issue of whether competition will
create stranded plant, and, if so, whether it should be recovered
from the LEC monopoly customers. Commission treatment of stranded
investment, if it occurs, may have a significant impact on the
LECs' financial health. That issue is beyond the scope of this
docket, but will have to be considered in the future. The
Commission has opened docket UM 731 to consider the proper
recovery of USWC plant.
How will the applications affect competition within the local exchange service area?
(a) Will the applicants' proposed service stimulate competition?
(b) How will local exchange providers respond to the
presence of competitive local service providers?
Positions of the Parties
Staff distinguishes between competition from facilities
based carriers and competition from resellers. Facilities based
carriers are those who, like the applicants, own their own
switches and at least some loop components. Staff asserts that
facilities based competition will provide customers in the
competitive zones with more choices, and new approaches to
configuring service offerings. Competition may also stimulate
innovation, which will benefit immediate users of the services
and ultimately all telecommunications users by providing greater
access to more efficient technology. Competitive entry will also
motivate the LECs to lower prices and improve efficiency for
services comparable to those offered by applicants.
USWC expects that competitive entry will stimulate
competition by offering alternatives to some customers. If
properly regulated, competition will eventually produce lower
prices, more choices, more innovation, and improved service
quality. The applicants' facilities will allow them to compete
not only for new customers, but also for USWC's existing market
share. USWC intends to use the pricing flexibility under its
existing AFOR and the competitive zone law to respond to
competition. USWC will also develop new pricing options and
increase advertising, marketing, and sales activities.
GTE contends that granting the applications will expand
competition in the target areas. Even in the best case, however,
competition would be "monopolistic," with multiple
providers offering essentially the same services and competing
through advertising and service packaging. The deployment of new
technologies and new services would become more market driven.
GTE asserts that the Commission should not attempt to
manufacture competition. The applicants seek significant levels
of aid and support from the incumbent LECs, usually at
incremental cost. The type and magnitude of market intervention
these requests would entail is contrary to the notion of
replacing a regulated monopoly system with a competitive market
approach. If technological and economic developments have made
state sanctioned monopolies obsolete, GTE believes that the
market should develop on its own. If there are areas where
telecommunications is a still natural monopoly, then the
rationale for the current regulatory system still exists.
Applicants and AT&T believe that entry will
stimulate competition, but stress that effective competition will
not develop overnight or on its own. The development of
competition depends on how the Commission resolves key policy
issues in this and related dockets. The applicants argue that
they need an appropriate economic costing analysis, a proper
imputation test, a fair local interconnection policy, immediate
unbundling, and true equal access. They also stress the
importance of the Commission's collocation and resale policies
for the development of competition.
If the applications are granted, the applicants assert that
AECs will stimulate competition by providing better, more
reliable service quality than the LECs. Competition on the basis
of service quality has been a key factor in the success new
entrants have experienced competing with incumbent LECs for
nonswitched services.
The applicants argue that, if the Commission creates the right
incentives, local exchange carriers should respond to competition
by reducing costs and becoming more efficient. If LECs are not
allowed to pass costs to other customers, the incumbents will
have to become more efficient and more responsive to customers
needs. The Commission should also not permit the LECs to recover
their common costs from the AECs in the price of the
interconnection elements. The full benefits of competition will
be realized only if all costs of the incumbents are subjected to
market pressures for greater efficiency. Finally, the applicants
note that the LECs will also have to upgrade their networks and
increase the quality and variety of their services in response to
competition.
Sprint believes that local competition will create new
market opportunities for both entrants and the incumbent LECs to
expand their service territories and the range of service
offerings, both of which create an opportunity to increase their
revenue and earnings. According to Sprint, competition in the
interexchange market has shown that an incumbent will respond to
new market conditions by developing new services and reducing
costs. How incumbent LECs respond to new entrants in the local
market will depend on how they are regulated. If a LEC cannot
pass costs on to its customers and still retain most of those
customers, the LEC will have to become more efficient and
responsive to its customers.
OCTA argues that competition offers improved service
and greater access to diverse facilities that could enhance
network reliability.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue II
Our decision to approve these applications to provide
competitive local exchange service is just the beginning in a
long process. Over time, AEC entry will increase the quality and
choice of service and decrease price for telecommunications
customers. Competitive entry will also promote deployment of new
technology and to foster innovation. In the long term, the
benefits from new technology and innovation will flow to all
users. In the short term, the main beneficiaries are likely to be
business customers. The incumbents will likely respond to
competition by lowering prices and creating new service packages.
They will also have to improve the quality of their service.
GTE argues that local exchange competition will be limited to
providers that offer the same services and compete through
advertising and service packaging. We do not believe this will be
the case. Even if it were, however, it is an initial stage in the
development of competition. Having a choice of providers and
service packages is a significant benefit to telecommunications
customers.
The development of competition depends, as several parties have noted, on appropriate conditions being established by the Commission. These conditions include elimination of entry restrictions, equal access to rights of way, local number portability, dialing parity, unbundling the monopoly local exchange network, comprehensive interconnection, cost based pricing by the incumbent, imputation, elimination of resale restrictions, and open technical standards. Not all of these matters are addressed in these dockets, but must be considered as we move forward in a competitive environment.
How will the application affect access by customers to high quality, innovative telecommunications service in the local exchange service area?
(a) What new or improved services will be offered by the applicants or the LECs?
(b) Will the applicants' application affect the quality of service offered by the LECs?
(c) What effect will the application have on economic
efficiency?
Positions of the Parties
Applicants point out that, initially, their service
offerings will approximate the services provided by the LECs.
Competition is likely to hasten the introduction of new services,
however. In other telecommunications markets, new and improved
services have been offered over time, many of which could not
have been predicted when the markets were first opened to
competition.
New services are likely to result from deployment of existing
technology as well as from technological development. MFS points
out that much of the technology deployed by competitive
providers, especially the use of fiber optics, had been available
for years, yet without any significant deployment until
competitive access providers entered various metropolitan markets
throughout the country. Companies can also innovate by providing
better service: quicker response times, redundant capacity,
creative billing solutions, and customer options. The LECs will
be forced to meet any service innovations that the AECs develop
in order to remain competitive.
The frequency of LEC service quality problems suggests that
the presence of AECs will encourage the LECs to upgrade their
service as well as to introduce efficiencies. Customers may be
unwilling to switch providers without a significant price
differential unless the LEC product is disappointing. Poor
service could seriously harm the incumbents. Thus competition
will have a positive effect on LEC service quality.
The applicants also argue that competitive entry will improve
economic efficiency in general. As markets move toward effective
competition, prices will be driven closer to the cost of the most
efficient service provider, improving static economic efficiency.
Moreover, the competitive process will speed the deployment of
new and better technologies in the most efficient way, improving
dynamic efficiency of telecommunications. Competition will also
increase the inflow of telecommunications capital into Oregon on
the part of the incumbents and new entrants, which will benefit
the economy of the state as a whole.
Finally, the applicants note that networks have properties
that magnify as they are interconnected. Because information is a
leading sector in the United States economy, an increase in the
number of networks available to transfer information can lead to
potentially greater economic gains than would increased
competition in other sectors.
The applicants challenge the LECs' assumption that competition
will result in decreased economies of scale and scope. According
to MCImetro witness Dr. Nina Cornell, USWC cost studies do not
reveal such economies except for the NAC. Moreover, the
theoretical benefits of such economies do not matter unless they
are passed on to the consumer in the form of lower prices,
because the incumbent monopoly firm is inefficient and there is
no competitive market incentive to keep costs in check.
The applicants contend that Staff ignores dynamic efficiency.
Staff does not account for possible market stimulation from the
greatly reduced prices it forecasts; nor does Staff acknowledge
that it is possible for competitors to bring new services and new
technologies to consumers more quickly and efficiently than the
LECs have been willing to do. Sprint concurs with the
arguments made by the applicants.
AT&T argues that competition will allow consumers
to benefit from innovation because it ensures the ascendancy of
the technology with the best service attributes and quality at
the best prices. At present, monopoly providers decide what
services will be offered in the local market. With effective
competition, consumers will decide.
According to AT&T, evidence from the interLATA market also
demonstrates that market forces drive application of the best
available technology. Sprint's aggressive entry into the long
distance market caused AT&T to accelerate deployment of fiber
technology and improve its methods of informing customers about
its fiber network. In the telephone equipment market, the black
rotary dial instrument has given way to portable phones,
answering machines, and fax machines, automatic re-dial, and a
host of other features and functions.
Staff also argues that competitive entry will encourage the LECs to deploy newer technologies like optical fiber more rapidly in the competitive zones. Competition should also encourage LECs and applicants to invest in research, because any sustainable competitive advantage will come through innovation. Where profitable, the benefits of competition could be available to customers outside the competitive zones as well. But if applicants merely resell the incumbent LECs' services and do not build their own facilities, it will exacerbate LEC bottlenecks and hinder customer access to telecommunications services.
GTE states that moving to a market based system will
necessarily change investment and service dynamics. Granting the
applications will affect service provided inside and outside the
competitive zones. According to GTE, the LECs will likely invest
on a more deaveraged basis if the applications are granted. They
will deploy new technologies in the competitive zones. Without
contribution from the more lucrative urban areas, investments
outside the zones would be based on the ability of those markets
to generate revenue to cover the cost of and return on
investments. Consequently, the implementation of a sound
universal service support program will be crucial for investment
dynamics.
As to whether competition will result in new or improved
telecommunications services, GTE argues that the introduction of
truly new services is driven by manufacturers' technological
developments. New technology is available to GTE, USWC, and the
applicants alike.
GTE believes that competition can result in improved quality
and in selective quality reductions. Rivals will compete for some
customers based on meeting high levels of performance and service
quality. However, the competitive market should also accommodate
those customers who will accept somewhat lower performance
parameters in exchange for lower prices. If the applications are
granted, GTE argues that all firms in competitive zones should be
subject to the same minimal level of service regulation by the
Commission, but the Commission should retain oversight of certain
critical services such as 911.
According to GTE, the effect of entry on economic efficiency will be mixed. GTE and USWC have constructed ubiquitous networks with nonduplicative facilities. Granting the applications will result in duplicate, overlapping construction. The total cost of providing local exchange service in the state will increase. Moreover, replacing a regulated monopoly system with a competitive market system will increase the riskiness of investment in telecommunications utilities. That, in turn, will increase the utilities' revenue requirement by increasing the return demanded by investors. GTE states that if a change in paradigm from regulation to competition is to produce any real economic efficiency gains, competition must develop naturally, so firms are free to respond to each other's actions. GTE urges that there should be no government compulsion in the market.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue III
In the near term, the applicants are not proposing the use of
any technology not already in place or planned by LECs,
especially in the Portland metropolitan area. When markets first
open to entry, the initial offerings are usually similar to those
already available; that will likely be the case here. As
competition takes hold, incumbents and new entrants will likely
compete on the basis of customer service. By their very presence
in the market, AECs will provide customers with enhanced
operational and strategic security, by serving as redundant
carriers. The fact that customers will have a choice of service
provider is also new. At the very least, competition should
improve the quality of service and enhance economic efficiency of
all participants in the local exchange market.
In the long term, competition should promote new products,
innovation, and the deployment of existing technologies not yet
in widespread use. ELI currently plans to offer intraLATA equal
access and physical collocation, in addition to the services
currently provided by the incumbents. MFS plans to offer the
services offered by the incumbents as well as credit card
calling, conference calling, voice mail, and E-mail, and
specialized customer services. Other new services may depend on
technological change, which is difficult to predict.
In a competitive environment, the LECs will be forced to
increase the variety of their services. Competition will
stimulate the LECs to provide new services, either in response to
AEC service innovations or on their own, in order to generate new
revenues. Effective competition will accelerate the rate of
innovation, for both new entrants and the incumbent local
exchange carriers alike. In response to competitive
pressures, USWC, for example, has announced plans to develop a
broadband network capable of offering customers multimedia
services and ATM and frame relay based services.
Competitive pressure will provide service quality standards
that are customer driven and market driven, and not dependent on
regulatory monitoring. Because customers will have a choice of
providers under a competitive regime, incumbent LECs will have to
improve the service quality as well, in order to retain customers
and market share. Service outages, repair delays, and delays in
service connections become costly for the incumbents when
customers can express dissatisfaction by changing carriers.
GTE points out that while competition will make high levels of
service quality available, some customers might choose a lower
level of quality or performance in return for a lower price. If
the lower service quality/lower price option is chosen by
informed consumers, the Commission has no objection to such a
tradeoff.
"Economic efficiency" includes both allocative
efficiency and technical or productive efficiency. Allocative
efficiency refers to the situation in which prices act as
appropriate signals for decisions that consumers and firms make.
The signals allow consumers to purchase the appropriate amounts
and kind of goods and services. Over time, competition will
enhance allocative efficiency by pushing prices closer to the
costs of providing a particular service.
Productive or technical efficiency refers to minimizing the
cost of producing a given level and quality of goods or services.
Cost containment may come from efficiency in internal operations
or technological change. Competition enhances technical
efficiency both by spurring technological innovation and
providing an incentive for firms to reduce costs.
"Economic efficiency" may also be judged in terms of
static and dynamic economic efficiency. Static efficiency is
similar to allocative efficiency. As to dynamic efficiency, we
agree with the applicants that competition will encourage the
deployment of new and better technologies over time. We also
agree that an increase in the networked properties of information
technology could lead to major economic gains for the state as a
whole.
GTE notes that granting the applications will result in
duplicate, overlapping construction of facilities, which is
economically inefficient. While this argument may have some
merit, it is also the case that the applicants are introducing
fiber optic based networks, while the incumbents' networks may
include a mix of newer and older technology. The facilities are
therefore not merely duplicative, but, to some extent, represent
the replacement of an older technology with a newer one. To
the extent that there is duplication, we find that the benefits
of competition outweigh the disadvantage.
GTE claims that the utilities' cost of capital will increase
because of the increased riskiness of investment associated with
a competitive market system. That remains to be seen. If the
utilities' revenue requirement increases as a result of
competitive local entry, we can address the issue in appropriate
rate proceedings. We are not convinced that such an increase is a
necessary outcome of the applicants' entry into the local
exchange market.
In theory, we agree with GTE that competition should be
allowed to develop naturally and without government compulsion.
At the same time, the incumbents have nearly 100 percent market
share in the local exchange market. Until there is indication
that competition will thrive on its own, it is not in the public
interest for regulators to withdraw completely.
We also agree with GTE that a sound universal service support
program is critical to telecommunications in Oregon. The
Commission has adopted a program in Docket UM 731 that addresses
GTE's concerns.
Other Considerations
(a) Should the Commission authorize the applicants to provide service within the entire area designated in the applications?
Issue IV(a) was resolved by stipulation.
Issue IV(b): If the application is approved, under what
circumstances may the applicants deny service to a potential
customer within the competitive zone?
Positions of the Parties
USWC asserts that AECs could effectively deny service
to customers the AECs do not want to serve by setting prices to
make the services unattractive. To require the AECs to serve all
customers who request service in the competitive zones, the
Commission would have to regulate the AECs' rates. The Commission
should avoid such a course of action.
Ideally, USWC believes that an AEC should hold itself out to
provide service to all customers within its authorized service
area. But USWC recognizes that, unlike public utilities,
competitive providers do not have an obligation to serve
ubiquitously within their service territories. USWC also
acknowledges that the AECs will need time to build their
distribution networks. For the present, USWC recommends that AECs
not be required to provide service.
MCImetro argues that the AECs should be permitted to
deny service to any customer if the potential customer does not
agree to reasonable conditions to ensure payment. The AECs should
also be able to deny service if they cannot reach a customer. If
the entrant does not have facilities that pass the customer and
cannot obtain an economic resale product or nondiscriminatory
unbundled network component from the incumbent LEC, there should
be no obligation to serve that customer. Likewise, if the entrant
has facilities that pass the customer but cannot get
nondiscriminatory access to the customer's premises, there should
be no obligation to serve. GTE, ELI, and Sprint take
a similar position.
MFS states that it is prepared to serve any customer,
including residential customers, within its license area. MFS'
goal is to provide universal access to its network, whether by
other service providers, subscribers, or competitors.
Staff argues that the Commission should leave it to the
applicants to determine whom they will and will not serve.
MCImetro did not apply for authority to serve residential
customers. ELI and MFS intend initially to offer services
targeted to the business customer market. The choice of all three
applicants to begin by serving only business customers would deny
service to potential residential customers within the competitive
zones, but this is a legitimate business decision for AECs to
make.
The Commission has authority to impose reasonable requirements
on AECs pursuant to ORS 759.015, 759.020, 759.030(1), and
759.050. But the Commission has generally adhered to the policy
of allowing market forces to determine prices and conditions of
service offered by competitive telecommunications providers. In
the long run, Staff believes that policy will best serve the
public and should be continued.
AT&T agrees with Staff. The new providers need time
to expand their networks. Once their facilities are in place,
they will have every incentive to serve customers requesting
service. Like all competitive companies, they will be guided by
commercially reasonable practices in refusing or terminating
service to customers.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(b)
We decline to impose denial of service criteria on the AECs at
this time. We agree with Staff and AT&T that it is
unnecessary to regulate the conditions under which the entrants
may deny service to potential customers. The LECs have expressed
concern that the AECs will deny service to customers whom they do
not wish to serve by pricing their services too high for the
relevant customers, by not providing information to potential
customers about the availability of their services, or by
imposing overly stringent credit requirements. LEC concern is
apparently rooted in a perception that it is unfair for the
entrants to deny service to some customers while the LECs are
under the obligation to serve ubiquitously throughout their
territory.
It would be unreasonable to require that new entrants serve
all customers, business and residential, within a given
geographic area until such time as their networks are in place to
do so. Once their networks are developed, the AECs should have no
incentive to refuse service to any customer. On the contrary,
they will need to expand their customer base in order to spread
their fixed costs over as many customers as possible. If denial
of service by AECs creates a problem in the future, the
Commission has statutory authority to impose conditions on the
AECs and would likely impose conditions similar to those under
which the LECs operate. Until competition is robust enough to
warrant relaxing the service obligations of the incumbent LECs,
however, we find the public interest best served by allowing
market forces to work.
Issue IV(c): Should the Commission impose requirements on
the applicants in addition to those in OAR 860, Chapter 32?
Positions of the Parties
GTE and USWC argue that all competitors and
incumbents should be subject to equal regulatory treatment within
the competitive zones. OAR Chapter 860, Division 32,
contains limited requirements for competitive providers. Those
rules were enacted when no competitive firms were providing local
exchange service. If the Commission grants the current
applications, it should declare that all Division 32 rules
pertaining to the provision of local exchange service by
utilities will also apply to applicants. Further, the Commission
should open a rulemaking for the purpose of modifying Division 32
or creating a new chapter to establish a set of rules appropriate
for competitive zones, which would apply equally to all firms.
Staff contends that the Commission should not impose
additional consumer protection or reporting requirements on the
applicants. Consumers who believe they have been poorly treated
by an AEC can opt to take service from the incumbent LEC or
possibly another competitive provider. Staff argues that the
Commission should leave it to market forces to deal with AECs who
provide poor service. If customers encounter special problems in
the future, the Commission could consider adopting additional
consumer protection rules or requirements for AECs. Staff does
not know what additional reporting requirements might be useful
for regulating AECs a the competitive market.
Staff notes that regulatory parity may be acceptable as a long range goal, but competition is not sufficiently robust throughout the service areas or even the proposed competitive zones to justify relieving the LECs of various requirements now imposed on them. Because most customers do not have effective alternatives to choose from, consumer protection requirements should continue to be imposed on the incumbent LECs. When the LECs present persuasive evidence that there is sufficient competition for local exchange services, then the Commission will consider relaxing the consumer protection requirements.
AT&T, ELI, MCImetro, MFS, OITA, and Sprint
concur with Staff. They argue that a competitive
market will regulate the behavior of entrants. The requirements
in OAR 860, Division 32, are sufficient to monitor the progress
of local exchange entry. If the Commission finds that existing
requirements are inadequate after it gains experience with a
competitive local exchange market, it may always impose
additional requirements. These parties urge caution in this area,
because unnecessary reporting requirements increase cost and may
limit competitive entry.
Commission Findings and Decision-Issue IV(c)
Consumer protection measures are critical when captive
ratepayers are forced to use monopoly service providers. To an
extent, those safeguards become unnecessary once customers have a
choice of carriers. Moreover, the AECs will also compete with the
LECs on service, and cannot hope to succeed unless they are
sensitive to consumer needs. Thus, the presence of alternatives
helps to protect consumer interests. Requirements in addition to
those in OAR Chapter 860, Division 32 are therefore unnecessary
at this time. We will revisit the issue of consumer protection
once competitive local exchange services have been more firmly
established.
The LEC goal of regulatory parity requires effective
competition for local exchange services. Once competition is
established, we will consider whether the consumer protection
requirements imposed on LECs should be relaxed.Issue IV(d):
Should the applicants be subject to the Oregon Customer Access
Fund Plan? If so, what conditions or procedures are necessary to
facilitate compliance with the Plan?
Issue IV(d) was resolved by stipulation.
Issue IV(e): What ancillary services should the applicants be required to provide?
(1) How will the applicants supply such services?
OAR 860-35-020 defines "ancillary service" as
"a service, such as billing and collection service" . .
. "which is performed by a local exchange carrier to
directly administer or support provision of the LEC's basic and
enhanced services. [Ancillary services] do not include the
provision of common administration such as human resources,
accounting, purchasing, inventory control, or other similar
functions." Ancillary services include, but are not limited
to, E-911 service, directory assistance, operator services,
operator assisted calls such as credit card and third party
billing calls, and directory listings.
Positions of the Parties
Staff and OITA recommend that the Commission not
require the applicants to provide any specific ancillary services
except access to E-911 service. The Commission should leave it to
market forces and the AECs to determine what ancillary services
they will provide.
ELI believes that the AECs should provide ancillary services that benefit the health and convenience of customers in general and which customers expect to receive from their local service provider, including E-911 service, telecommunications relay services, operator and directory services. ELI will provide a number of other ancillary services, using a combination of its own resources and the resold services of the incumbent LECs.
MFS intends to provide ancillary services such as
directory assistance, operator services, calling card, conference
calling, and voice mail, but does not believe that the Commission
should require the AECs to provide ancillary services.
MCImetro believes that the AECs should be
required to provide access to operator service, directory
assistance, and emergency services, as well as unified telephone
directories. MCImetro will use a combination of its own resources
and resold service of the LECs to provide these services.
AT&T contends that the Commission should rely on competitive market to determine what services the new entrants will provide. Consumers will probably demand such services, but the Commission should not require an AEC to provide them.
Sprint argues that the AECs should be required to
provide operator services, directory assistance, and emergency
services.
GTE argues that the principle of regulatory parity also
applies to ancillary services. In the competitive zones, any
requirement to provide ancillary services should be the same for
all firms. In a market environment, the government should not set
any requirements. On that principle, GTE argues that 911 service
should be the only ancillary service that LECs and AECs are
required to provide.
USWC maintains that the Commission should only
mandate provision of essential services: a local
telecommunications network facility, feature, or function that
competitors cannot realistically duplicate or obtain from an
alternative source, and to which reasonable access is necessary
to enable competition. The only requirement the Commission should
impose on AECs is terminating access on their networks.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(e)(1)
We agree with Staff that E-911 service is the only ancillary service that AECs should be required to provide. Public health and safety concerns support that requirement. We expect that the AECs will offer the remaining ancillary services because their customers will demand them. Again, we prefer to let the market dictate what services AECs offer. The record indicates that the applicants will supply ancillary services with their own equipment or through arrangements with the LECs.
GTE argues that if the Commission requires the AECs to provide
only E-911 service, it should require no more from the LECs. OAR
860-32-020 allows tele-communications utilities to petition for
authority to abandon service and permits the Commission to relax
the LEC consumer protection and service requirements on a case by
case basis. Until competition has been established, however, we
will not consider lifting the ancillary service requirements on
the LECs.
Issue IV(e)(2): What ancillary services, features, and
functions should the LECs be required to make available to the
applicants?
Issue IV(e)(2) was resolved by stipulation. The LECs agree to treat the AECs as they treat independent local exchange carriers (ILECs) for purposes of making ancillary services available. The resolution of this issue is consistent with our decision that AECs should have co-carrier status with other local exchange service providers. Throughout this order, we have mandated treatment for the AECs that is analogous to the treatment the ILECs receive from the LECs.
Issue IV(f): What intercompany compensation arrangements
are needed for calls placed within an exchange, and calls placed
between exchanges within the competitive zone?
The most controversial issue in this proceeding relates to the
method for compensating carriers for costs associated with the
termination of local exchange traffic. Because interconnection
costs are a major cost component for new carriers, the terms and
conditions of these arrangements are critical to the viability of
entrants and the emergence of local exchange competition.
In evaluating the various intercompany compensation proposals,
the Commission is guided by ORS 759.015, which requires, inter
alia, a balanced program of regulation and competition.
Toward that end, intercompany compensation should be
nondiscriminatory, simple to administer, and neutral from a
technological standpoint. It should also foster economic
efficiency, create incentives for infrastructure development, and
ensure that all carriers are fairly compensated.
Summary of Positions
Reciprocal Usage Sensitive Compensation
USWC and GTE propose reciprocal compensation
arrangements based on the access charge rate structure in effect
for toll traffic. USWC recommends that AECs pay a switching
charge and an interconnection charge for local and
toll traffic terminating at a USWC end office switch or delivered
to a USWC tandem for delivery to a USWC end office switch. These
charges would be assessed for each minute of use and are
reciprocal; that is, USWC will pay an AEC a switching and
interconnection charge for each local and toll minute of use
originated by USWC customers and delivered to an AEC switch.
USWC's proposal also contemplates that AECs will pay a carrier
common line charge (CCLC) for all intraLATA and interLATA toll
traffic terminated on USWC end office or tandem switches. The
CCLC is part of USWC's current switched access rate structure and
is assessed on a minute of use basis. Like the local switching
and interconnection charges, the CCLC would be reciprocal. The
CCLC would not apply to local traffic.
Finally, USWC proposes that the Commission approve a
nonreciprocal Interim Universal Service Charge (I-USC) of 0.85
cents per minute for all local traffic delivered by an AEC and
terminated on a USWC end office switch. The proposed I-USC is
discussed more fully beginning on page 38 of this order.
USWC's proposed interconnection rates are as follows:
Local and EAS Calls Rate (Cents per Terminating Minute)
Local Switching 1.0881
Interconnection 0.0582
I-USC 0.8500
Total 1.9963
Toll Calls Rate (Cents per Terminating
Minute)
Local Switching 1.0881
Interconnection 0.0582
Carrier Common Line Charge 2.0400
OR Carrier Access Fund Charge 0.4810
Total 3.6673
GTE also recommends reciprocal interconnection
compensation based on the rates included in its switched access
tariff. GTE does not recommend that the CCLC or an I-USC apply to
the termination of local or "EAS-like" traffic. The
interconnection rate paid by an AEC for terminating local
exchange traffic on a GTE switch would be 2.05 cents per minute.
According to GTE witness Dr. Edward Beauvais, the
interconnection compensation structure should not distinguish
between calls that are intraexchange or interexchange within a
competitive zone or interexchange outside of a competitive zone.
However, such an approach requires eliminating the CCLC and
rebalancing current rates. Dr. Beauvais recommends that the
Commission consider repricing issues in docket UM 351. If
switched local service competition is authorized before such
repricing occurs, all interexchange interconnection traffic
should be assessed the full switched access tariff rate,
including the CCLC. Intraexchange traffic would not be subject to
the CCLC under those circumstances.
Dr. Beauvais emphasizes-and
most other parties concur-that the pricing structure in a
competitive telecommunications environment must ultimately move
away from arbitrary classifications such as toll, access usage,
local usage, and EAS. These classifications would be replaced by
a single integrated rate structure applicable to all switched
traffic. As USWC points out:
[L]ocal interconnection is no different technically and
conceptually from any other kind of interconnection. Compensation
for the use of one carrier's network by another should be the
same regardless of how the originating carrier rates the traffic
to its customers. In the competitive world, there will be little
distinction between local and toll at the state level.
Dr. Beauvais observes that an integrated price structure for
interconnection avoids the enforcement and definitional problems
inherent in current differential pricing structures, conveys
proper economic signals to customers, and is simpler and more
equitable to administer. In addition, it will provide the pricing
flexibility necessary for telecommunications providers to succeed
in an increasingly competitive environment.
Reciprocal Usage Sensitive Compensation-Opposing Arguments
ELI, MFS, MCImetro, AT&T, McCaw, OCTA, Sprint, and TCG criticize the proposal to use switched access charges as the compensation structure for interconnection. These parties argue that the proposed rate structure (a) imposes a price squeeze on entrants; (b) precludes opportunities for local exchange prices to decline;
(c) creates barriers to competition because of the lack of
reciprocity; (d) requires traffic measurement capabilities that
are unavailable and costly to implement; (e) is unrelated to
underlying costs; (f) inhibits competition by skewing traffic
patterns; and (g) forces entrants to imitate the network
architecture of the LECs. These arguments are addressed below.
(a) Price Squeeze. According to Dr. Cornell, a
"price squeeze" is a relationship between prices that
can arise whenever a monopoly supplier of an input to other firms
also competes to sell a retail service which incorporates that
bottleneck input (or essential function). If the monopoly
supplier sets the price of an essential function at a level such
that the retail end user price does not recover both the price
for the essential function and the remaining costs to produce the
service, a price squeeze exists. Under a price squeeze,
competitors who must purchase the essential function from the
monopoly supplier face a barrier to entry because they cannot
cover their costs at the price charged by the monopolist for the
retail service.
ORS 759.050(5)(b) is designed to prevent price squeezes by
establishing an imputation price floor for services sold by
telecommunications utilities within competitive zones. It
requires that the price for a service offered by a
telecommunications utility may not be less than the TSLRIC of
nonessential functions plus the price of the essential functions
necessary to provide the service.
MCImetro and TCG presented evidence to
demonstrate that the interconnection rates proposed by USWC and
GTE will result in a price squeeze. Dr. Cornell and TCG witness
Dr. Paul Teske compared USWC's proposed interconnection rate with
measured usage rates available to USWC's retail business
customers under various calling packages. Both analyses disclose
that a USWC business customer subscribing to measured service
pays less to originate and terminate a local call than an
AEC would pay to USWC just to terminate a local call.
Dr. Teske also compared USWC's and GTE's proposed
interconnection rates with the retail rates paid by customers for
a number of other services. His analysis indicates that:
Based on his analysis, Dr. Teske contends that the
interconnection rates proposed by USWC and GTE create a classic
price squeeze, which effectively precludes AECs from competing
for local business and residential customers. In every instance,
the rate that AECs would pay to terminate calls is greater than
the effective calling rate that USWC and GTE customers now pay to
receive retail service. Thus, AECs would experience negative
operating margins even before incurring any of the costs
associated with originating, switching, or transporting the call.
These additional costs further exacerbate the substantial losses
AECs would encounter. Dr. Teske concludes that local competition
is not viable under such circumstances.
Several parties emphasize that the usage based interconnection
rates proposed by USWC and GTE will create an underlying cost
structure that is incompatible with the flat rate environment for
retail local exchange service in Oregon. If usage sensitive
charges are assessed for every minute of use, it is uneconomic
for an AEC to serve customers beyond a given usage threshold. As
demonstrated by Dr. Teske's analysis, the USWC and GTE proposals
effectively create a price squeeze at higher usage levels,
relegating AECs to serving low volume customers that are least
likely to be interested in obtaining service from a competitive
provider.
In its posthearing brief, GTE alleges that Dr. Teske's interconnection/retail rate comparison is misleading and inaccurate because it (a) hinges on assumed usage levels not based on actual traffic studies; (b) reflects only traffic flowing in one direction, and does not account for offsetting revenue; and (c) fails to take into account the mandatory EAS additive. GTE claims that, if the correct figures had been used, Dr. Teske's comparisons would have yielded positive margins at all assumed levels of usage. It further emphasizes that switched access rates are subject to change in the pending
UM 351 investigation, and that GTE has proposed reductions in
its switched access rates that may extend to both local and toll
traffic.
TCG disputes GTE's claims regarding the validity of Dr.
Teske's price squeeze analysis. It maintains that a price squeeze
still exists for a large segment of the relevant market even
after the EAS additive is included in the comparison. TCG's
calculations show that GTE business customers making more than
1182 minutes of calls per month will have an effective retail
rate less than GTE's proposed 2.05 cpm interconnection charge.
Likewise, GTE residential customers making more than 662 minutes
of calls per month-4 to 5
calls per day-will have effective retail rates less than 2 cpm,
resulting in negative margins for competitors. TCG maintains that
anticipated reductions in rates generated by competition will
only exacerbate the price squeeze by reducing the threshold level
beyond which AECs cannot effectively compete.
USWC witness Dan Purkey performed a series of
imputation analyses to demonstrate that USWC's proposed
interconnection rate will not result in a price squeeze. Mr.
Purkey conducted service specific imputation studies for flat
rate simple business service, flat rate complex business service,
business measured service, PBX trunk service, Centrex line
service, DSS service, and Public Access Line Measured Service. A
separate analysis was made for each service using the Average
Direct and Shared Residual Cost (ADSRC) methodology and the
Average Service Incremental Cost (ASIC) methodology. In addition,
an imputation analysis inclusive of all USWC business services
was performed using the ADSRC approach. In every case, the
imputed price floors derived were significantly less than USWC's
current tariff rates. According to Mr. Purkey, these results
demonstrate that USWC's interconnection proposal will allow AECs
to compete with USWC for local exchange business services.
ELI, TCG, and others maintain that USWC's imputation studies improperly manipulate cost and price data and ignore applicable imputation requirements in order to demonstrate that switched access compensation will not create a price squeeze. ELI states that USWC: (a) assumes incorrectly that certain inputs are nonessential instead of essential (and therefore improperly imputes USWC's cost instead of the tariff rate);
(b) fails to include certain essential functions and nonessential service specific costs; and (c) relies on hypothetical usage and price data. Furthermore, USWC's analyses do not reflect the actual telecommunications marketplace and disguise the fact that the proposed switched access compensation structures will render local competition uneconomic by barring entrants from creating profitable services.
To illustrate the alleged shortcomings in USWC's imputation analysis, ELI witness William Montgomery prepared a revised imputation study. Mr. Montgomery used the same general method as Mr. Purkey, but incorporated the following assumptions: (a) intraoffice traffic is included for imputation purposes;
(b) terminating transport is treated as an essential function
and imputed at USWC's tariff rate; (c) number portability and
directory listings are considered essential functions and imputed
at $4.00 and $0.75 per line per month, respectively; (d) USWC is
assumed to use its pricing flexibility to offer "Custom
Choice" discounts of 30 percent to business customers;and
(e) USWC's proposed I-USC is disallowed. Mr. Montgomery's
imputation analysis included flat rate business service,
Centrex/PBX/DSS usage, and all business services combined. His
adjustments generally yield higher price floors, and therefore a
smaller margin between the amount an AEC must pay for
interconnection and the amount charged by USWC for the retail end
user service. In several instances, the AEC margin is negative;
that is, the imputation price floor exceeds the USWC tariff rate
for the retail service. Dr. Montgomery contends that negative
margins affirm the existence of a price squeeze, since AECs lose
money on every minute of use.
(b) Impact on Local Rates. AT&T, ELI, OCTA
and MCImetro contend that USWC's proposed interconnection
rates will require it to raise local rates, resulting in an
upward pricing spiral. Dr. Cornell explains how pricing
interconnection above cost prevents competition from lowering
retail prices:
Since interconnection is a service that cannot be
self-supplied, the price paid, whether in cash or in kind, is a
permanent part of the cost structure of each carrier. Thus if
either carrier has to pay more than cost to the other carrier,
the amount above cost remains permanently embedded in the cost of
local exchange service. This is because what is a price to the
carrier charging that amount is a cost to the carrier paying it.
Not only does USWC want to embed some amount above cost in
local exchange rates permanently, but it also wants to impose a
price squeeze. This means that USWC is trying not only to recover
all of the "contribution" from local calling that it
would have gotten had it provided the end to end call, but it is
trying to recover some of the "contribution" that it
would have gotten if it had supplied the access connection as
well. Any policy that allows USWC to continue to collect
"contribution" even when it does not provide the
service from which the "contribution" is derived is a
policy that directly hinders the achievement of greater
efficiency in telecommunications. USWC loses a significant
incentive to compete for the customer, given that it can retain
the "contribution" even if it does not incur the costs
to provide the service. If USWC is allowed to retain the
"contribution" without performing the service, that
portion of the total telecommunications bill can never fall due
to competitive pressures.
Because of these circumstances, Dr. Cornell argues that USWC's
interconnection proposal will not lead to competitive entry. If
entry does occur, it will not be sustainable. Absent competitive
pressure, Dr. Cornell observes that costs will not decline.
ELI further contends that there is no economic
rationale for adopting switched access charges as the
compensation structure for local exchange service. According to
Mr. Montgomery, the primary rationale for using switched access
charges is that LECs need contribution to compensate for
universal service and carrier of last resort (COLR) obligations.
In an emerging competitive environment, contributions to fund
universal service should be collected in a competitively neutral
manner, not through inefficient carrier access charges that limit
or foreclose competition.
(c) Lack of Reciprocity. MCImetro maintains that
USWC's compensation proposal is not reciprocal because AECs will
not be able to charge as much as USWC for interconnection.
According to Dr. Cornell, nonreciprocal compensation creates a
barrier to entry because it requires entrants to absorb higher
costs than incumbents. In order for AECs to attract customers,
they must price below the rates of the incumbent LEC or offer a
better service at the same price. If an AEC is forced to pay a
higher interconnection price, it must be more efficient than the
incumbent even to match the incumbent's price, let alone price
below the incumbent. Therefore, a lack of reciprocity is similar
to a price squeeze because it keeps equally efficient carriers
out of the market.
Dr. Cornell also emphasizes that requiring a more efficient
carrier to charge less for interconnection effectively forces
that carrier to transfer its efficiencies to its competitors. In
order for the market to send correct information to consumers
about which firm is more efficient, the more efficient firm must
be permitted to pass on the benefits of those efficiencies to its
own customers, not the customers of its competitors.
(d) Measurement Related Costs. USWC witness Owens
testified that the technological means for measuring terminating
local exchange traffic was not available to that company at the
time of hearing. USWC anticipated that it would develop a method
to generate the necessary call records by the end of 1995. It
argues that the additional investment in measurement capability
is necessary to enable carriers to manage their networks in a
competitive environment. Networks already have the capability to
measure intercompany toll rated traffic, and the cost of adding
local measurement is expected to be modest and incremental. USWC
points out that existing LECs are already pursuing measurement
arrangements. Also, much work has been done to accommodate GTE's
entry as a primary toll carrier and to measure the integrated
toll and local traffic exchanged with wireless carriers.
Until its measurement system is in place, USWC proposes to
work with AECs to determine the local traffic exchanged between
networks. Mr. Owens states that originating carriers can supply
measurements of local traffic delivered to terminating carriers
so that the latter can bill the traffic terminated on their
systems. USWC is willing to rely on AEC measurements until a more
precise measuring system is in place.
GTE, on the other hand, states that its existing
systems can measure local traffic at relatively low cost. GTE can
also carry mixed local and toll traffic on two way trunks,
provided that the rate for terminating local traffic is the same
as the rate for terminating toll. If the terminating rates for
local and toll differ, it will be necessary to use separate trunk
groups for the two types of traffic. The current industry
practice for handling toll and EAS traffic is to use separate
trunk groups.
Staff contends that measurement is necessary in a multiprovider environment. Because AECs will interconnect different types of traffic -including intrastate toll, interstate toll, local, and EAS-it is important to record the type of call and jurisdiction so that the appropriate intercompany compensation and end user billings can be made. Staff opposes allowing originating carriers to estimate the "percentage of local use" (PLU) in lieu of actual measurement because of the potential for carriers to misreport traffic.
Opponents of usage sensitive interconnection pricing contend
that the costs associated with developing a system to measure
intercarrier local traffic will compromise economic efficiency
and unnecessarily increase the total cost floor for local
exchange services. According to MCImetro and TCG,
cost studies in the state of Washington disclose that adding
measurement and billing costs more than doubles the cost of end
office switching. Furthermore, USWC estimates that the cost of
implementing its new measurement system in Washington will be
more than three times the amount now spent to measure switched
access minutes of use. Dr. Cornell emphasizes that it is
inefficient for firms to develop measurement and billing
arrangements that significantly increase the cost of doing
business, especially since traffic between networks will tend to
be in balance over time. TCG adds that, if traffic is roughly in
balance and both carriers' interconnection rates are the same,
the expense of measuring is wasted because both carriers are
simply billing each other the same amount. Even if traffic is not
in balance, the degree of imbalance must justify the costs of
measuring and billing.
ELI, OCTA and MCImetro also observe that
measured compensation will force new entrants to incur additional
costs to audit and correct errors in measurement and billings.
ELI witness Walter Cook and Dr. Cornell testified that the
carrier access billings currently received by interexchange
carriers contain many errors and must be amended on a regular
basis. Audit costs are a significant expense for interexchange
carriers and can be expected to increase the cost of providing
local exchange service for AECs. Furthermore, AECs familiar with
auditing procedures for switched access will not be able to rely
on that expertise because the proposed measurement system for
local exchange traffic differs from the system for switched
access terminations.
Applicants further contend that measurement related costs will
impose a greater relative burden on entrants than on incumbent
LECs. In order to provide service, entrants either have to incur
the expense of installing measurement equipment in their networks
or absorb the cost of terminating intercarrier traffic. In
addition, AECs will have smaller volumes of traffic over which to
spread measurement, billing, and auditing costs for the
foreseeable future. In contrast, the amount of local traffic
delivered from LEC to AEC facilities will represent a much
smaller percentage of the incumbent's total traffic.
(e) Cost Causation. ELI and TCG assert that
usage sensitive compensation is inappropriate because the costs
of facilities used to provide interconnection are largely a
function of capacity. These arguments are addressed below.
(f) Traffic Patterns. TCG and MCImetro argue
that the measured compensation proposals offered by USWC and GTE
will distort local exchange competition by encouraging
competitors to serve customers with higher volumes of incoming
calls in order to equalize interconnection revenues. In a
competitive market, new entrants may be expected to serve as many
customers as possible, regardless of usage patterns, in order to
maximize overall revenues. AECs are likely to evaluate potential
customers not only on local exchange use, but on overall
telecommunications usage, including toll and vertical services.
Customers with high traffic volumes are most likely to be
interested in exploring various competitive offerings in order to
minimize their total telecommunications costs. MCImetro and TCG
contend that measured compensation creates an incentive to avoid
interconnection charges and encourages AECs to serve low volume
customers and customers that rely heavily on inbound traffic. The
problem is exacerbated by the fact that AECs would pay higher
interconnection rates than incumbent LECs under the proposals
forwarded by USWC and GTE.
(g) Network Architecture. Several parties argue that
the switched access compensation structure proposed by USWC and
GTE will skew the technology and architecture choices of
entrants, thereby reducing or eliminating the benefits derived
from competitive entry. At the outset, entrants can be expected
to terminate a much higher percentage of their traffic onto the
networks of the incumbent LECs. A switched access rate structure
will force entrants to mirror as many of those rate elements as
possible and will affect AEC decisions about the architecture to
employ. According to Dr. Cornell:
Switched access charges are composed of a series of rate
elements charged for the use of different piece parts of the
incumbent's network to terminate a call. Except for the rate
elements designed to pay "contribution," if a piece
part is not used, then the rate element is not charged. The
proposals to use switched access charges for compensation mostly
include the same requirement. Thus, the entrant would only be
allowed to charge for the same categories of costs that
the incumbent claims are the costs of providing service.
Suppose an entrant placed only a single switch, using much
more "loop" plant than the incumbent. The total cost to
it to terminate a local call for the incumbent may or may not be
less than the incumbent's costs, but those costs may be in
different categories from those used by the incumbent. If the
only costs the entrant can recover in its local interconnection
tariff are switching and transport costs, however, it will be
handicapped relative to the incumbent, and may be prevented from
recovering all of its costs regardless of whether they are less
than or equal to the incumbent's costs. Because of the inability
to recover its costs using its preferred architecture it will
face an incentive to try to mirror the architecture of the
incumbent, even if it were not the most efficient architecture.
Interim Universal Service Charge
As noted previously, USWC proposes that the Commission approve
a nonreciprocal Interim Universal Service Charge (I-USC) of 0.85
cents per minute for all local traffic delivered by an AEC and
terminated on a USWC end office switch. USWC witness Jeffrey
Owens explains the charge as follows:
The proposed interim universal service charge is a result of
the substantial difference between USWC's residential and
business exchange rates. USWC has been able to maintain this
differential as a result of its historic role as a single
provider of these services in its exchanges, wherein each
business customer has provided support to roughly 2.43
residential customers. The advent of competition in the local
exchange will ultimately require USWC to equalize the rates for
residence and business exchange services-as competition inevitably will drive the prices of
these services closer to cost. Initially, most AECs are likely to
serve business exchange customers almost exclusively-although
some AECs, who have access to the distribution networks of cable
companies, are likely to serve a comparable mix of business and
residential customers as USWC. If USWC is to maintain the
differential between its business and residential rates during a
transitional period, it is essential that the Commission impose
an interim universal service charge on those AECs who choose to
avoid the burdens associated with serving the residential market.
USWC contends that the I-USC is not a "keep whole"
charge designed to protect it from competitive loss, but is
required to maintain consumer equity and competitive neutrality.
Mr. Owens emphasizes that the I-USC will only recover a portion
of the support flow lost from business customers who will be
served by AECs. It will not recover contribution provided by
toll, access, and vertical services that are lost when a business
exchange customer takes service from an AEC.
USWC proposes that the I-USC be discontinued if an AEC (a) has
a sustained ratio of residential to business customers that is
equal to or greater than USWC's comparable ratio; (b) provides a
telecommunications service which has a demographic and geographic
penetration similar to the relevant USWC exchange; (c) serves its
residential and business customers using its own facilities; and
(d) provides Federal Link-Up and Oregon Telephone Assistance Plan
service to its residential customers.
USWC regards the I-USC as a temporary mechanism that cannot be
sustained in a competitive environment. It states:
The monopoly era approach of allocating large amounts of
revenue requirement to interconnection rates to keep all
residential rates below cost is not viable going forward. There
must be a transition downward in interconnection rates, as other
rates are rebalanced commensurate with specific, identified
universal service requirements. The current pure contribution
rate elements of access should be replaced with targeted,
competitively neutral funds to meet the affordability needs of
low density and low income segments of the market. The industry
and the Commission must use interconnection charges sparingly as
needed to preserve universal service.
USWC envisions that the I-USC will be reduced over time as the
company is able to rebalance its residential rates to levels that
recover direct cost plus an appropriate level of shared and
common overhead costs. It urges the Commission to rebalance
rates, reduce the subsidies inherent in residential exchange
rates and reapportion contribution levels among the company's
services.
USWC acknowledges that the Commission is presently reviewing universal service issues in docket UM 731 and will likely entertain rate rebalancing proposals in docket UM 351. Nevertheless, it recommends that the I-USC be approved without delay. USWC contends that its competitors will quickly gain market share in the Portland metropolitan area where USWC business revenues are concentrated. If the
I-USC is not implemented, USWC states that it will be
effectively deprived of the opportunity to earn a fair rate of
return, because competitors will "strip off large portions
of [business] revenues," leaving USWC to serve residential
and rural customers at unprofitable rates.
Interim Universal Service Charge--Opposing Arguments
Applicants and several intervenor parties recommend that the Commission reject the proposed interim universal service charge proposed by USWC. Opponents of the
I-USC contend that the charge is not cost based and is
unnecessary to compensate LECs for universal service obligations.
These parties assert that USWC has not quantified the level of
support necessary to protect universal service or demonstrated
that the funds generated by the I-USC would be used for that
purpose. They further maintain that, in a competitive
environment, all support for universal service should be made
explicit and collected in a manner that is competitively neutral.
MFS argues that there is no support in the record for
USWC's claim that an implicit cross subsidy of residential
service by business service exists, and consequently, no
evidentiary foundation to justify adopting the I-USC. MFS notes
that the TSLRIC cost data presented by Staff discloses that USWC
provides both business and residential service above cost. In
contrast, the ADSRC cost methodology used by USWC to demonstrate
that residential rates are below cost includes additional common
and overhead costs and differs from the cost methodology approved
by the Commission in docket UM 351. Given the shortcomings in
USWC's cost study, and absent evidence that Staff's TSLRIC
calculations are incorrect, MFS asserts that there is no credible
evidence to support the I-USC.
Sprint maintains that USWC's method of calculating the
I-USC is "inherently suspect and faulty." Sprint claims
that the I-USC is necessarily inflated because it presupposes
that all AEC customers are former customers of USWC; i.e., that
USWC will lose a business exchange line for every line obtained
by a competitor. According to Sprint witness Dr. Richard Purkey:
this presumption of a static market (or "zero sum
game") clearly ignores new growth, and as well ignores the
fact that US West will undoubtedly collect an IUSC from AEC
customers who were never customers of US West, but were rather,
former customers of GTE or another independent phone company.
Thus, the assessment of the IUSC obtains for US West not only
compensation for alleged competitive losses, but a new and
potentially large revenue stream as well.
ELI and TCG make similar arguments, emphasizing
that USWC's approach assumes that all future, as well as current,
business lines would be USWC customers.
In addition, several parties argue that the criteria proposed by USWC for reducing or eliminating the I-USC are arbitrary and subject to manipulation. TCG also observes that the conditions for waiving the charge permit USWC to impede competition by burdening new entrants with costs that will remain in effect for an indefinite length of time at USWC's discretion.
Opponents of the I-USC acknowledge that there are definable
customer groups that may require a subsidy to remain on the
network. Rather than have USWC administer such subsidies,
however, the Commission or another independent entity should
assume responsibility for determining the appropriate subsidy
mechanism and the customer groups eligible to receive support.
Generalized surcharges such as the I-USC are an inappropriate
means of funding universal service. AT&T and ELI recommend
that the Commission reject USWC's arguments regarding universal
service and COLR until such time as USWC quantifies the level of
support associated with those obligations. Mr. Montgomery states:
The policy question concerning whether and how much
contribution is required to protect universal service is whether
a particular group of customers would still be served at the
option of the incumbent carrier, without any COLR obligation,
even if some component of the ratepayer's service is below the
piece part cost of that service. Piece part cost studies cannot
answer this question. The answer requires looking at the overall
cash flow derived from the customer, considering all sources of
revenue.
* * * * * * * * *
The COLR concept assumes that being the provider of telephone
service is a liability, when in fact the market shows that it is
an asset. LECs like USWC claim that being a COLR is a liability
wherever cost studies seem to indicate that access prices are
below the costs of this specific "service." Telephone
company cost studies treat "basic exchange access" as a
separate service, when, in fact, access lines are what provide
the economies of scope in telecommunications. Many services can
be provided once access is available but not without it. LEC cost
studies typically examine only some of the economic factors that
would be needed in order to determine whether one class of users
was subsidizing another class. Even if it were assumed that these
piece part cost studies are completely accurate, they are not
sufficient to set contribution policies with respect to
competitive entrants.
Staff agrees with the I-USC in concept, but disagrees
with USWC's method of computing the charge. Staff's approach
incorporates different EAS rates and a different cost
methodology. If the Commission approves an I-USC, Staff
recommends that USWC and GTE file proposed I-USC rates and
supporting cost data as separate tariffs.
Flat Rate Compensation
TCG proposes a compensation arrangement that allows
local exchange traffic to be transferred to the terminating
carrier at its last point of switching at no charge to the
originating carrier. This arrangement would apply equally to AECs
and incumbent LECs. Local exchange traffic transferred to the
terminating carrier at locations other than the terminating
carrier's last point of switching, however, would be terminated
at a flat monthly charge that recovers only the terminating
carrier's cost of transporting the traffic from the transfer
location to the last point of switching (including any inter-
mediate switching). In other words, TCG recommends bill and keep
compensation for end office termination and a flat rate port
charge for termination at the tandem switch.
Dr. Teske proposes bill and keep for end office terminations
because AECs are unlikely to build facilities to an end office
unless there are sufficient traffic volumes to warrant
construction of those facilities. Under those circumstances,
there is likely to be a community of interest in the calling
area. Consequently, traffic flows between AECs and LECs will tend
to be closer to equilibrium. Tandem interconnections, on the
other hand, entail additional switching and trunking costs that
justify a flat rate port charge until traffic reaches a rough
equilibrium. This approach addresses concerns relating to traffic
imbalance by providing a transition mechanism to bill and keep
without incurring the problems associated with traffic
measurement. In addition, the end office/tandem pricing
differential is designed to encourage investment in and
development of AEC facilities to the end office. Dr. Teske
maintains that this investment will enhance network redundancy,
leading to a more reliable "network of networks" and a
more robust telecommunications infrastructure.
TCG's proposed flat rate charge would require carriers to make
available DS1 capacity switch ports for terminating traffic at
the tandem and end office levels. The ports would be priced on a
flat monthly basis and would reflect differing end office and
tandem functions. Carriers would measure the peak busy hour of
each month to determine the relative traffic flow over the DS1
facility and allocate port charges using the deploying carrier's
tariffed rate. By monitoring peak busy hour usage, carriers will
be able to ascertain when traffic is balanced and can make the
transition to bill and keep for tandem interconnections at that
time. Dr. Teske calculates the capacity based rate for tandem
ports by multiplying the per minute cost of tandem switching and
(average) transport by an assumed DS1 usage of 216,000 minutes
per month. In a recent interconnection compensation case in
Washington State, this formula yielded a monthly flat rate charge
of $130 for a tandem DS1 port.
Dr. Teske states that TCG's proposed compensation structure
better reflects how interconnection related costs are incurred
than does usage sensitive pricing. The bulk LEC interconnection
related costs result from "lumpy" investments in
switching and interoffice trunking capacity that are designed to
meet peak usage requirements, while the cost of carrying off peak
traffic is essentially zero. As a consequence, usage sensitive
compensation schemes substantially overstate the cost of
completing calls during most times of the day. Moreover, flat
rate capacity charges are a more logical means of assessing call
completion charges in a competitive market since competition
forces price structures to match underlying cost structures.
ELI concurs with TCG's position regarding cost
causation in telecommunications networks. Mr. Montgomery states:
The new technologies are less sensitive to call distances and
to call usage. Whereas usage rate structures measure only these
factors, the underlying costs are becoming relatively more
sensitive to the capacity demanded, rather like the "demand
charge" in kilowatts in an electric service pricing
structure, compared with usage sensitive kilowatt hours. Fiber
optics technologies are much less distance sensitive than the
predecessor metallic, analog technologies. In the long distance
market, all of the major carriers now offer optional postalized
rates (i.e., rates that do not vary by the distance
covered, as postage stamp rates), so that a call from Portland to
Washington, D.C., costs the same as a call from Portland to Salt
Lake City. These postalized rates recognize, among other things,
the reduced sensitivity of the fiber optic transport technologies
used by interexchange carriers. Local carrier networks are, of
course, evolving so that most calls already transverse fiber
optics technologies at some point, and the networks placed by
entrants like ELI will be predominantly fiber optics. Likewise,
switching and call control systems are also much less
"traffic sensitive" and more "non-traffic
sensitive" than outmoded costing models like jurisdictional
separations rules currently recognize. Digital switches are
predominantly "non-traffic sensitive" as are new call
control systems like Signaling System 7.
TCG and ELI also point out that capacity based reciprocal
interconnection compensation arrangements afford all carriers
greater retail pricing flexibility than usage based compensation
structures. Despite the fact that the retail telephone market in
Oregon is dominated by flat rate local calling, AECs will be
unable to offer flat rate local calling if they must pay per
minute charges to terminate traffic. If usage sensitive pricing
is adopted, AECs will be forced to choose between offering minute
of use pricing and garnering little or no market share, or
offering flat rate calling and losing money. Effective local
exchange competition is unlikely under either scenario. Capacity
based charges, on the other hand, permit all carriers to develop
both flat rate and measured usage options for local calling,
including time of day and volume discounts. This type of pricing
flexibility is not possible in an environment where the dominant
carrier imposes per minute interconnection charges, because those
charges effectively establish a price floor for all carriers
operating in the market.
Finally, Dr. Teske observes that flat rate capacity charges are simpler to administer because they entail only the monthly measurement of traffic and billing of a fixed charge. Per minute charges, on the other hand, require complex and costly measuring, recording and billing capabilities that few carriers now possess.
Flat Rate Compensation-Opposing Arguments
GTE argues that TCG's proposed flat rate charge for the
switching component of interconnection is a departure from the
cost methodology adopted by the Commission in Phase I of the UM
351 docket. GTE asserts that the UM 351 methodology develops
switching costs on a per minute of use basis, and is incompatible
with TCG's claim that interconnection costs are not usage
sensitive. Dr. Beauvais notes that flat rate charges might be
reasonable as a temporary step while measured compensation is put
in place. However, incorporating the proper capacity and pricing
assumptions is crucial to ensure that carriers receive proper
compensation for their services.
MCImetro also disagrees with TCG's proposed flat rate
port charge for terminating traffic at the tandem. It contends
that the proposal will encourage providers to extend facilities
to the end office instead of the tandem in order to avoid
interconnection charges, without regard to the efficiency of a
particular architecture for a given market. MCImetro asserts that
TCG's proposal implicitly assumes that incumbent LECs have
efficiently designed networks. It also distorts the market by
sending signals that are unrelated to minimizing cost or
maximizing efficiency.
One Way Compensation
Staff recommends a compensation arrangement that
requires AECs to pay switching and transport access charges to
LECs for EAS and local calls terminated on LEC facilities. AECs
would not be compensated for any terminating traffic. OITA
concurs with Staff's compensation proposal.
Staff witness Thomas Turner offers three reasons for opposing
reciprocal compensation. First, the AECs, unlike the incumbent
utilities, are not subject to extensive rate, service and cost
regulations and do not have universal service or COLR
obligations. Second, reciprocal compensation is not available to
other entities that lease or own telecommunications facilities,
including radio common carriers (RCCs), Shared Telecommunications
Service (STS) providers, coin telephone providers, and private
line networks. Last, Mr. Turner states that reciprocal
compensation may create an incentive to "game the
system" at LEC expense, by obtaining authority, leasing a
few lines, and receiving compensation from the LEC for all
incoming traffic. While such a scenario may seem unlikely, Staff
believes it is prudent to anticipate that carriers might take
advantage of such an opportunity.
Staff does not believe that AECs will be adversely impacted by
the lack of compensation for traffic terminated on their
networks. Mr. Turner observes that RCCs have experienced
phenomenal growth despite the fact that they receive no
compensation from LECs. In addition, AECs have a strong growth
potential because they face few regulatory restraints and can
become "one stop" telecommunications providers by
integrating terminal equipment, radio communications, and long
distance communications together with targeted local exchange
services. Staff states that reciprocal compensation may be
appropriate when the "regulatory landscape is equal,"
but recommends that the Commission proceed cautiously to avoid
jeopardizing affordable service.
As a policy matter, Staff recommends that the interconnection compensation mechanism adopted in this proceeding should be interim in nature. It recommends that the Commission open an investigation to consider a permanent solution within a year after the first AEC is authorized to provide local exchange service. Staff proposes that AECs pay from 1.3 to 1.6 cpm to terminate traffic on USWC's network, depending upon local transport distance. Staff recommends that the Commission adopt the rate proposed by GTE for traffic terminated on that carrier's network.
One Way Compensation-Opposing
Arguments
ELI, MCImetro, MFS, TCG, Sprint, McCaw, OCTA and
AT&T oppose the one way compensation scheme recommended
by Staff. They make the following arguments:
(a) Because Staff's proposal allows only LECs to charge for
calls terminated on their network facilities, it will foreclose
effective competition and perpetuate LEC domination of local
exchange markets. Staff's proposed compensation structure
attempts to achieve "regulatory symmetry" by denying
AECs compensation for interconnection, but ignores the fact that
the incumbent LECs possess 100 percent of the market for switched
local exchange service. Dr. Cornell argues that regulation should
acknowledge differences in market power. Moreover, to the extent
that LEC rates incorporate cross subsidies to support universal
service and ubiquity, the proper regulatory response is not to
impose uneconomic costs on entrants in a manner that impedes
competition. Rather, the appropriate response is to identify
valid policy goals, quantify the level of support necessary to
achieve them, and devise a competitively neutral means of
funding. The pending universal service and unbundling/repricing
dockets are the appropriate forums in which to consider these
issues.
(b) According to MFS, Staff's one-way compensation
approach is undermined by the cost evidence presented by Staff
witness Turner. Mr. Turner's calculations disclose that
residential customer rates paid by incumbent LEC customers are
above cost. If LECs are in fact experiencing a positive margin on
residential service, then universal service does not impose a
burden on the incumbent, but rather conveys a benefit. MFS
observes that Mr. Turner did not address, and could not quantify,
how holding the incumbent LECs harmless from paying compensation
relates in any direct, quantifiable manner to specific universal
service costs. Nor did Staff discuss whether universal service
support-to the extent such a
subsidy exists-is being provided by the LECs in the most
economically efficient manner. Consequently, there is no
justification for denying AECs compensation for terminating local
exchange traffic as a surrogate for universal service
obligations.
(c) ELI, MCImetro and McCaw argue that Staff's
attempt to compare AEC interconnection arrangements with the
compensation structure paid by RCCs is misplaced. McCaw points
out that FCC rules require mutual compensation for
interconnection services established between wireless and
wireline competitors. While current interconnection tariffs do
not provide for mutual compensation for cellular carriers, this
situation must change to advance the goal of competitive
neutrality. Toward this end, several parties, including Staff and
the LECs, advocate eliminating use and user restrictions and
moving toward an environment where all interconnecting entities
purchase network functionalities from the same unbundled tariffs.
Staff's one way compensation scheme is incompatible with this
objective and should be rejected.
MCImetro further argues that nonreciprocal compensation
is a major reason why cellular carriers have traditionally been
perceived as providing discretionary, high priced service rather
than as a substitute for traditional local phone service.
According to Dr. Cornell:
Cellular carriers were forced to be niche providers, serving a
supplementary purpose only, because they were denied true
co-carrier treatment, subjected to interconnection charges that
priced them out of being able to effectively compete for local
exchange service.
MCImetro and McCaw assert that, if the regulatory goal is
uniform treatment of all local carriers without distinctions
based on technology, the Commission should opt for mutual
compensation instead of Staff's one way compensation proposal.
ELI contends that comparisons between AECs and RCCS are inapposite because cellular telephone service is not a direct substitute for the local dial tone services proposed by the applicants. Mr. Montgomery states that positive cross price elasticity does not exist between local dial tone and cellular service because the market demand served by cellular cannot be readily duplicated by fixed wireline alternatives. Rather than exhibiting positive cross elastic effects, the demand relationship between cellular and wireline service is complementary; that is, decreases in the price for cellular phones or cellular usage increase demand for wireline network. This condition explains why cellular services have enjoyed "phenomenal" growth, despite usage charges that far exceed local dial tone charges even where the wireline service is provided under usage sensitive rates. It also explains why cellular service has been relatively unaffected by the lack of reciprocal compensation for calls from wireline networks to cellular phones.
(d) Opponents of one way compensation also dispute Staff's
claim that one way compensation is appropriate for applicants
because providers of STS services, private coin operated
telephone service, private lines and farmer lines are not
compensated for traffic terminated on their equipment. ELI and
TCG point out that the services mentioned by Staff differ from
the facilities based local services proposed by the applicants in
terms of cross price elasticity, the insignificance of call
terminations (e.g., many coin phones do not permit inbound
calling), and other specific economic characteristics. For
example, the relationships between demand for local dial tone and
the local service of STS services are not true cross elasticities
between comparable products. Because the local component of STS
is essentially resale of local dial tone, it represents
arbitrage, not sustainable economic cross elasticity.
(e) Staff's compensation proposal is premised on the
assumption that AECs will capture 10 to 20 percent of USWC's
local exchange business market in the competitive zones by the
year 2001. Opponents argue that Staff's analysis is flawed
because it fails to consider actual market experience,
underestimates line stimulation, uses outdated
information, fails to take into account likely cost savings, and
relies on faulty analogies between AECs and LECs. These arguments
are discussed under Issue No. I.
Bill and Keep Compensation
ELI, MFS, MCImetro, AT&T, and OCTA recommend
adoption of a "bill and keep" compensation arrangement
for the exchange of local and EAS traffic, at least for an
initial period to allow local exchange competition to take hold. TCG
agrees that bill and keep offers many of the same advantages as
its proposed flat rate approach. Under bill and keep, no explicit
monetary compensation is required for the exchange of traffic
terminated on each carriers network. The proposal, also known as
mutual traffic exchange, or payment in kind, requires that each
carrier absorb the cost of traffic originated and terminated on
its own network.
Under a bill and keep arrangement, AECs and incumbent LECs will establish trunk groups between each other's networks with Signaling System 7 (SS7) interconnection. The AECs and incumbent LECs will terminate local and toll traffic over these trunk groups. Termination of local calls will be compensated on an
in kind basis. Compensation for terminating toll calls
will be compensated based on tariffed switched access charges.
The mix of traffic terminated over these trunks may be rated
based on a percentage local usage factor (PLU), similar to the
percentage interstate usage (PIU) factor that has been used for
many years to rate interstate and intrastate traffic between
interexchange carriers and LECs. Alternatively, separate toll and
local trunks may be utilized.
Bill and keep is premised on the assumption that intercarrier
traffic flows will be in balance. If traffic is not in balance,
the carrier terminating more calls will incur higher costs.
Proponents of bill and keep acknowledge that a new entrant will
likely terminate a higher percentage of its originated calls on
an incumbent's local network than the incumbent will terminate on
the new entrant's network. This does not mean that traffic flows
will be imbalanced in favor of the entrant, however. It is the absolute
volume of calls terminated by each carrier, not the relative
percentage of calls terminated, that is relevant for
ascertaining whether traffic flows are in balance.
ELI witness Montgomery emphasizes that intercarrier traffic is
likely to be balanced in a competitive co-carrier environment
because AEC customers will exhibit calling patterns very similar
to those of LEC customers in the same area. Moreover, unless an
AEC's incentives concerning which customers to serve are
artificially distorted by discriminatory compensation rules,
traffic flows are more likely to be balanced than in the case of
existing EAS routes. Applicants point out that there is no
evidence in the record to support the claim that terminating
traffic will not be in balance.
With respect to the issue of traffic balance, MFS witness Peter Schulz testified regarding the local traffic exchanged between MFS Intelenet of New York, Inc.
(MFS-NY) and NYNEX in New York City. New York is the only
jurisdiction with any significant history relating to switched
local traffic exchanged between an entrant and an incumbent LEC.
Over the first five months of 1995, 54 percent of the local
traffic exchanged between the two carriers was terminated on
MFS-NY facilities, and 46 percent was terminated on NYNEX
facilities. In every month, NYNEX terminated more traffic with
MFS-NY than vice versa. Similarly, traffic balance studies
conducted in Washington State disclose a 53:47 split in EAS
traffic terminations, a difference of plus or minus three
percentage points.
Proponents of bill and keep point out that it is the
predominant compensation plan among LECs in the United States for
terminating calls in EAS areas. InterLEC terminations of local
calls typically occur when an EAS route is established between a
calling area served by a regional Bell operating carrier and an
area served by a nonBell, or independent, carrier. Bill and keep
has worked because the revenue settlements are simple: Each LEC
recovers the costs of call origination and termination from its
own customers. EAS compensation can also involve division of
costs between LECs for trunking and other facilities, but there
is no per call compensation between carriers. A similar situation
would prevail if bill and keep is applied to traffic exchanged
between AECs and LECs. ELI witness Montgomery states that bill
and keep will:
vastly simplify the Commission's new responsibilities in an
environment of emerging competition, and it is highly compatible
with new incentive forms of regulation. The Commission will not
have to develop a new form of compensation for existing or future
EAS routes, nor will it have to try to differentiate between EAS
and directly competing LECs connections -a task which may be impossible economically. The most
critical price squeeze issues go away with [bill and keep] and
the Commission can devote its time and resources towards further
rationalization of local, toll and access pricing without being
continually embroiled in disputes among competitors.
In this context, MFS points out that cash compensation
arrangements such as those proposed by the LECs and Staff will
generate disputes concerning the rates LECs should impute for
terminating traffic. The disagreements that have surfaced in this
case regarding the imputation suggest that this issue is
extremely contentious. Bill and keep compensation arrangements
would eliminate the time and effort associated with resolving
those disputes.
Aside from administrative simplicity, ELI points out that bill
and keep avoids the possibility that incumbent carriers will use
intercompany compensation as a means to leverage their market
power to increase an entrant's cost structure. If applied on an
interim basis, bill and keep permits regulators to observe the
development of local compensation and take the time necessary to
fashion compensation plans that may be feasible in the long term.
As noted above, bill and keep for local call termination is
compatible with the current switched access charge structure for
toll calls. For example, if ELI hands a long distance call to
USWC, ELI will pay the same switched access charges as any of the
current long distance carriers such as AT&T.
Proponents also contend that bill and keep provides the correct economic incentive for LECs and AECs to design and operate their respective networks to achieve maximum possible efficiency over time. Bill and keep requires each carrier to absorb the cost of all traffic terminating on its network. Therefore, carriers have an incentive to become more efficient by using technology and network architecture to minimize interconnection costs. Usage sensitive compensation schemes, on the other hand, do not create the proper economic incentive to reduce termination costs because cost responsibility is shifted to the carrier originating the calls. Also, as noted above, usage sensitive compensation forces new entrants to mimic the technology and architecture of the incumbents, even though it may be inefficient.
MCImetro argues that bill and keep is the only compensation
arrangement that creates incentives for incumbent LECs to
cooperate in developing number portability. Without number
portability, AECs will be unable to attract customers with a
significant amount of incoming calls, creating a traffic
imbalance that disadvantages LECs. Number portability will permit
AECs to serve customers with incoming and outgoing calls, thereby
ensuring that traffic remains in balance.
Dr. Cornell and others also emphasize that bill and keep
eliminates the incentive for new entrants to solicit customers
with specific calling patterns. If compensation arrangements for
traffic termination impose a disproportionate cost burden on
AECs, those carriers will have an incentive to attract customers
with more incoming than outgoing calls in order to minimize
termination charges. Effective competition will occur sooner if
this distortion is not present.
Finally, proponents argue that bill and keep saves on
transaction costs associated with traffic exchanged between
carriers. Bill and keep is the least costly method of
compensating carriers for terminating traffic because carriers
are not required to incur costs associated with measuring,
billing and collecting terminating access charges. Thus, bill and
keep will result in a lower total cost floor and drive local
exchange rates as low as possible.
Bill and Keep Compensation-Opposing Arguments
USWC, GTE, OITA and Staff all oppose bill and
keep as a method of interconnection compensation. These parties
argue that bill and keep is inappropriate in a competitive
environment because it allows AECs to use the facilities of the
incumbent LEC for free. According to Dr. Beauvais, bill and keep
is uneconomic because new entrants are able to utilize the
terminating facilities of an interconnecting carrier at a zero
marginal price, creating both static and dynamic inefficiencies.
Bill and keep is inefficient in a static sense because AECs will
rely on the existing facilities of the incumbent LEC, rather than
building out their own networks or seeking alternatives for the
delivery of traffic from other potential suppliers such as cable
TV companies or electric utilities. Bill and keep is also
inefficient in a dynamic sense, because a zero price will cause
over consumption of access services and reduce the incentive to
employ new, lower cost technologies as they become available.
USWC, GTE and Staff also maintain that traffic between
carriers will not be balanced. While bill and keep arrangements
might be appropriate from a theoretical standpoint if traffic
between carriers is in balance and terminating access
charges are equivalent, USWC contends that these conditions are
unlikely to occur in practice. As a consequence, one of the
providers will not recover the full cost of terminating traffic
from the other provider.
According to USWC witness Owens, interoffice traffic between
LEC and AEC central offices will be out of balance because of two
market realities - the fact
that AECs can choose to serve particular types of customers, and
because different customers have different patterns of
originating and terminating traffic. Other factors that will
generate a traffic imbalance include (a) the different mix of
businesses and residences in the communities served by the
central offices of the two different carriers; (b) monthly
fluctuations in AEC traffic mix that will occur with customer
growth; and, (c) the fact that different AECs are unlikely to
have the same level of success marketing their service to every
customer class. According to USWC, these factors will cause the
traffic flow between carriers to vary on a monthly basis.
USWC also argues that, even if the volume of traffic exchanged
between carriers is roughly equal, LECs will nevertheless
experience higher costs to terminate traffic. Arguing in support
of the I-USC, Dr. Harris states that AECs are selectively
deploying facilities to serve low cost business customers, and
leaving the LECs with the obligation of serving high cost
customers He argues that interconnection compensation should
reflect these underlying cost differentials as well as the value
that AECs derive from network redundancy and back up capacity
provided by the ubiquitous networks of the LECs.
USWC adds that bill and keep should not be used because USWC
will incur substantially greater transport costs than the AECs
due to differences in the respective networks of the providers.
According to Mr. Owens, AECs are likely to interconnect at USWC's
tandem switches and use USWC's transport network to reach USWC
end offices throughout its dispersed service territory. In
contrast, traffic terminated by USWC on AEC networks will be
confined to a relatively compact serving area. Greater use of
USWC's transport network by AECs will cause USWC to incur
substantially greater transport costs that cannot be recovered
under a bill and keep arrangement.
GTE argues bill and keep is essentially a "forced
barter" arrangement that fails to reflect the fact that the
value of the interconnection services being exchanged are not the
same. Because of "inevitable imbalances in traffic" and
"differing cost structures of the various firms," it is
not possible for a bill and keep compensation arrangement to
provide payments that are equal in value.
Opponents of bill and keep also claim that in kind
compensation is incompatible with a multiprovider
telecommunications environment. Identification, measurement and
pricing of services exchanged is the common business practice
observed by competitive firms. USWC witness Dr. Robert Harris
emphasizes that no other industry operates on the premise that
traffic interchange will be balanced; rather, firms negotiate
exchange rates and price the services they provide for each
other. He observes:
The central tenet of economics is that prices play a
critically important role in the allocation and distribution of
goods and services in a market economy. I agree with Staff's
opposition to "bill and keep" because it violates that
principle. Furthermore, the use of bill and keep is without
empirical foundation in a market economy. There are countless
instances in which two businesses provide services to each other.
In most cases, businesses price those services and collect
payment based on the actual volume of services provided, just as
they would any other customer. In a few cases - when bartering is involved-firms trade services in
kind, without exchanging money payment; even then, the firms keep
an account of what has been provided by each party to the
exchange, so that each party knows what is "owed" the
other party. In other words, mutual compensation . . . is not
observed as a business practice in competitive industries.
Although bill and keep is currently used for EAS traffic
exchanged between LECs, opponents argue that in kind arrangements
are inappropriate in a competitive environment. Staff witness
Turner emphasizes that EAS compensation arrangements were
designed to accommodate utilities with similar regulatory
obligations and are reasonable because they avoid the costs and
complexities of joint compensation, minimize EAS costs, and
promote universal service and customer fairness. AECs, on the
other hand, are not subject to the same regulatory constraints as
the LECs. Dr. Harris further emphasizes that existing EAS
compensation was never predicated on the assumption that traffic
would be balanced, but rather that each LEC would be made whole
for its costs through the revenue requirement, ratemaking, and
separations process.
Staff also argues that, because bill and keep allows
"free access" to the networks of incumbent LECs, it
will create incentives for IXCs to obtain the "lowest priced
access by routing traffic via the AEC's free interconnection
arrangement." In other words, Staff contends that toll
traffic handed off from an IXC to an AEC and then terminated on
an LEC network, may be improperly designated as local traffic to
avoid payment of switched access charges.
Finally, USWC argues that bill and keep will create incentives
for LECs to look outside their traditional exchange boundaries
for new customers and to terminate traffic from these customers
under existing bill and keep arrangements. USWC states that such
LEC "cream skimming" would not be in the public
interest.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(f)
Based on the evidence and arguments presented, the Commission
finds that compensation for the exchange of local traffic between
the applicants and the LECs in the competitive zones should be
based on bill and keep arrangements for an interim period of not
more than 24 months. We are persuaded that bill and keep has
fewer shortcomings than other compensation proposals made in this
case and will function as a reasonable compensation mechanism
during the initial stages of competitive entry into the local
exchange market. At the same time, we recognize that bill and
keep is only a temporary means of accommodating local exchange
competition and that a more permanent intercompany compensation
mechanism must be developed as competition progresses.
Accordingly, we find that an industry work group should be
created to address interconnection compensation issues.
The task of the work group shall be to formulate proposals for
implementing a reciprocal interconnection rate structure
applicable to all switched telecommunications traffic by the end
of the 24 month period. We agree with Dr. Beauvais and others who
maintain that telecommunications customers will not realize the
full benefits of competition until existing classifications such
as "toll," "local," and "EAS" are
eliminated in favor of a single integrated pricing structure. The
advantages of an integrated pricing structure are that it is
nondiscriminatory, technologically neutral, and does not entail
enforcement problems inherent in current rate structures. It also
conveys the correct economic signals, thereby creating incentives
for each carrier to make the most efficient use of its network
and resources. It is not clear, however, that the transition to
an integrated price structure can be accomplished in one step.
The work group shall be responsible for evaluating the extent to
which a phased approach is necessary, and shall develop
appropriate recommendations regarding the timing and
implementation of rate structure changes.
The interconnection compensation work group shall consist of
representatives from USWC, GTE, Staff, MFS, ELI, MCImetro, and
other interested parties, including consumer groups, ILECs, IXCs,
and other competitive providers. Staff shall submit a report to
the Commission every six months detailing the progress of the
work group. In addition, the applicants, USWC and GTE shall
conduct and submit periodic traffic studies of local and EAS
traffic exchanged with other carriers. The first study shall be
submitted within six months from the date of this order.
Additional traffic studies shall be submitted every six months
thereafter. This information can be used by the work group to
develop its recommendations regarding reciprocal compensation
arrangements for terminating traffic.
Our decision to adopt bill and keep on an interim basis will allow the applicants to enter the local exchange market while the Commission concludes a number of important dockets that will have a major impact on interconnection rates paid by telecommunications providers. Before substantial progress can be made toward a new interconnection pricing structure, the Commission must complete the pending universal service and unbundling/repricing dockets. As noted above, we recently issued Order
No. 95-1103 in docket UM 731, establishing a method of funding
universal service in Oregon. Phase II proceedings are now
underway in that docket to resolve implementation issues. In
addition, hearings have recently concluded in UM 351. An order
specifying the level and extent of unbundling of LEC services
will be issued shortly. A likely outcome of that docket will be
additional proceedings to determine the extent to which LEC rates
must be rebalanced to correspond with the unbundling and pricing
policies adopted in UM 351. In our opinion, there must be
substantial resolution of these matters before a more permanent
compensation structure for interconnecting all carriers can be
implemented.
There are several other advantages to implementing bill and
keep as an interim compensation mechanism. Because bill and keep
is the dominant practice for terminating EAS traffic between
adjacent LEC exchanges in Oregon and throughout the nation, it is
the least difficult compensation arrangement to implement from an
administrative standpoint. The inherent simplicity of bill and
keep makes it a sensible choice as a transitional compensation
mechanism until a more comprehensive interconnection rate
structure can be implemented.
In this context, we note that the reciprocal compensation proposals made by USWC and GTE contemplate that AECs will file access tariffs and cost support data. Presumably, this information would have to be audited before the applicants could begin providing service, to ensure that the proposed interconnection rates exceed TSLRIC, but are not unreasonably high. Evaluating AEC cost data would be extremely time consuming and could delay competitive entry for several months. The interim bill and keep arrangements authorized in this order avoid that process and hasten the provision of competitive local exchange service without any adverse consequences. At the same time, the Commission retains authority pursuant to ORS 759.050(3) to require the AECs to make all filings necessary to justify continued certification as competitive local exchange providers.
Interim bill and keep arrangements will also avoid
transactions costs associated with cash based compensation
methods because interconnecting carriers will not incur the
expense of measuring, collecting, and auditing traffic. This is
advantageous during the initial stages of competition, because
measurement costs impose a greater relative burden on new
entrants, who must spread the capital cost of such systems over
much smaller volumes of traffic. The record discloses that
interexchange carriers incur significant costs to collect and
audit switched access minutes calculated by LECs.
USWC argues that the system it is developing to measure local traffic is inexpensive, but the record suggests otherwise. Cost studies filed by USWC in Washington State show that the cost of local end office switching is more than doubled by the addition of measurement and billing costs. Moreover, in Washington, USWC estimated that the proposed new system would be over three times more costly per minute than the cost to measure switched access minutes of use. Even if we were inclined to adopt a minute of use compensation structure at this time, USWC has not demonstrated that its proposed method of measuring local traffic is reasonable. Until such a system is in place, the LECs could rely on AEC measurements of originating traffic. That process, however, would presumably entail the same type of costs now incurred by IXCs to audit switched access minutes.
The Commission also notes that a number of other jurisdictions
have concluded that bill and keep is a reasonable method of
compensating carriers for the exchange of local traffic on an
interim basis. On October 31, 1995, the Washington Utilities and
Transportation Commission adopted bill and keep as an interim
compensation measure for local exchange carriers in that state. WUTC
vs. U S WEST Communications, Inc., et al., Docket Nos.
UT-941464, UT-941465, UT-950146, & UT-950265, at 29-36. On
July 24, 1995, the California Public Utilities Commission adopted
interim rules requiring LECs and competing local carriers to use
bill and keep for interconnection compensation for a one year
period. Orders Instituting Rulemaking and Investigation on the
Commission's Own Motion for Local Exchange Service, Docket
Nos. R. 95-04-043 and I. 95-04-044, 163 PUR 4th 155 (Cal.
P.U.C. 1995). On February 23, 1995, the Michigan Public Service
Commission adopted a modified approach, authorizing bill and keep
unless there is a traffic imbalance greater than five percent. In
the Matter of the Application of City Signal, Inc., Case
No. U-10647, 159 PUR 4th 532, 543-48, 577 (Mich. P.S.C.
1995).
In reaching the decision to use bill and keep as a
transitional compensation mechanism, the Commission has
considered the opposing arguments raised by USWC, GTE and Staff.
For the reasons discussed below, we find those arguments
unpersuasive.
(a) The claim that bill and keep allows "free use"
of LEC facilities is predicated on the assumption that AECs will
terminate more traffic on LEC networks than vice versa. There are
no traffic studies in the record to substantiate that claim. On
the contrary, the record indicates that traffic exchanged between
AECs and LECs is likely to be within a few percentage points of
equilibrium. In fact, traffic studies performed by MFS in New
York disclose that where there has been an imbalance, more
traffic has been terminated on AEC facilities than on the
facilities of the incumbent utility.
We agree with the applicants that bill and keep compensation
is appropriate for the early stages of competition because it
will not affect traffic flows or influence a carrier's choice of
customers. The usage based rates proposed in this docket, on the
other hand, would foster traffic imbalances by distorting an
entrant's incentives to serve certain types of customers.
Notwithstanding LEC arguments to the contrary, we believe that,
if the AECs are able to attract and serve customers in the
Portland metro area with calling patterns that are similar to
adjacent USWC or GTE customers residing in the same area, traffic
flows in a competitive co-carrier environment are likely to be in
balance.
Even if traffic flows are out of balance, we agree with Dr.
Teske that the degree of imbalance must justify the cost of
measuring, billing and auditing the traffic. As noted above,
there is not enough information in the record to enable the
Commission to ascertain the costs associated with those
activities.
(b) GTE and USWC argue that, because bill and keep
compensation allows AECs to use LEC facilities at a
"zero" price, it discourages AECs from using new
technology and results in the over consumption of access
services. We disagree. To begin with, the argument assumes that
entrants will consume more access services than the LECs; in
other words, that traffic flows will not be in balance. As noted
above, the record does not support that claim.
Second, we are not convinced that bill and keep will foster
inefficiency in the near term. Bill and keep simply requires each
carrier to absorb the cost of traffic terminating on its system.
Since those costs are ultimately passed along to customers, it
would seem that each company has an incentive to reduce
interconnection costs to remain competitive. Conversely, the
minute of use arrangements proposed by USWC, GTE and Staff may
not create a similar incentive, since termination costs are borne
by other carriers.
Third, new entrants have a significant incentive to build out
their own facilities regardless of the method of interconnection
compensation. The applicants have already invested in substantial
facilities and are presumably interested in maximizing profits by
serving as many customers and exchanging as much traffic as
possible. They are unlikely to implement business plans based on
"over consumption" of LEC resources because of the
obvious uncertainties associated with such a strategy. Moreover,
the applicants are unlikely to survive as local exchange
providers unless they are capable of providing consistently high
quality telecommunications service. By building their own
facilities, the applicants will have greater control over service
quality provided to their customers and will be less reliant on
the networks of the incumbents.
(c) We are not persuaded by the claim that bill and keep is a
"forced barter" arrangement because it places the same
value on the terminating facilities of each carrier. GTE and USWC
fail to recognize that usage sensitive compensation yields the
same result. Because usage sensitive pricing imposes
interconnection costs on competing carriers, there may be little
economic incentive to lower those costs. In fact, depending on
how the pricing structure is designed, interconnection rates
could gravitate to the level of the least efficient carrier in
the marketplace. On examination, both Dr. Cornell and USWC
witness Purkey agreed that usage sensitive pricing could yield
equal interconnection rates over time.
For similar reasons, we are not persuaded by USWC's argument
that bill and keep forces it to absorb higher interconnection
costs because of greater use of its transport facilities. USWC's
argument presumes the existence of a specific network
configuration that may or may not exist once the applicants begin
operations. Furthermore, even if USWC is correct, it does not
force the conclusion that bill and keep is an unreasonable
interim interconnection arrangement. From a regulatory
standpoint, USWC is entitled to earn a reasonable rate of return
on the assets it has dedicated to utility service. That does not
mean that a separate charge must be levied for every
functionality or asset placed in service.
We also disagree with Staff's claim that bill and keep
compensation will cause carriers to misreport toll traffic in
order to avoid payment of switched access charges. While it is
conceivable that a carrier would risk decertification by
deliberately misreporting traffic, that possibility already
exists, and will exist as long as the cost of terminating toll
traffic exceeds the cost of terminating local calls. To eliminate
the possibility for misreporting traffic altogether, the
Commission will, however, have to equalize termination rates,
either by raising local termination rates or lowering toll access
rates. The record discloses that raising local termination rates
to switched access rate levels would create a price squeeze and
preclude AECs from entering the local exchange market. Lowering
toll access rates, on the other hand, may require a substantial
realignment of LEC rates to reduce the level of contribution now
incorporated in switched access charges. As emphasized above, the
ultimate solution is to develop a single interconnection rate
structure applicable to all carriers. That process, however, will
take time to accomplish.
Aside from the problems noted above, the Commission has a
number of additional concerns with the usage sensitive and flat
rate compensation methods proposed in this case:
(a) The record indicates that the minute of use compensation
proposals offered in this proceeding do not accurately reflect
the manner in which interconnection costs are incurred.
Telecommunications networks are engineered primarily to meet
system capacity requirements and are largely comprised of
nontraffic sensitive costs. Minutes of use consumed during off
peak periods thus have a marginal cost of nearly zero.
Consequently, a compensation structure that charges the same
amount for each minute of use does not convey the accurate price
signals and may lead to uneconomic consumption.
By declining to adopt the usage sensitive rate structures
presented in this case, we do not intend to foreclose future
consideration of measured compensation arrangements that require
reciprocal cash payments. The work group established to examine
interconnection compensation should carefully evaluate the need
for reciprocal payments in a competitive environment that
includes not only facilities based carriers such as the
applicants, but also other types of telecommunications providers.
(b) The usage sensitive rates proposed by USWC and GTE would
make it extremely difficult, if not impossible, for the
applicants to compete for medium to high volume customers. Usage
rate comparisons presented by Drs. Cornell and Teske disclose
that, beyond a moderate usage level, the rates in USWC and GTE
retail tariffs are lower than the proposed interconnection rates,
effectively placing AECs in a price squeeze. Since customers with
higher usage are most likely to consider using an alternative
telecommunications provider, the proposed interconnection rates
create a significant barrier to competition.
Minute of use interconnection pricing is also problematic
because of the predominately flat rate pricing environment for
local service in Oregon. As long as flat rate local service is
required by law, usage sensitive rates need to be carefully
structured to avoid creating a price squeeze. Usage sensitive
switched access rates have worked well in the toll market because
the retail price structure for toll has traditionally been based
on measured usage. Because that is not the case for local service
in this state, precautions must be taken to ensure that future
usage sensitive rate proposals do not produce anticompetitive
effects.
The interconnection rates recommended by Staff and the LECs
are also likely to distort normal traffic patterns by encouraging
applicants to serve customers with a high volume of incoming
calls in order to avoid interconnection charges. Normally, AECs
would be expected to also target customers with a significant
percentage of outgoing calls in order to maximize the revenue
potential from services such as toll. By disrupting traffic flows
within the local exchange market, the usage sensitive rates
recommended by the LECs and Staff will result in inefficiency and
customer confusion.
(c) We are not persuaded by the imputation analyses offered by
USWC to show that its interconnection proposal will not result in
a price squeeze. First, it is not clear that USWC used the
correct cost methodology to perform its studies. Mr. Purkey
acknowledged that the ADSRC methodology differs from the cost
methodology approved by the Commission in Phase I of docket UM
351, but asserted that the ASIC methodology used in his analysis
mirrored the UM 351 approach. Our understanding is that ASIC and
the UM 351 methodology differ in several respects. Second, Mr.
Purkey's analysis assumes that certain inputs to the imputation
analysis are nonessential rather than essential functions. In
Order No. 95-313, we held that all service elements should be
treated as essential until such time as an LEC is able to
demonstrate that viable alternatives exist in the relevant
market. Third, it is not clear that the imputation analyses
include all of the necessary functions or the correct usage and
price data.
Because of these concerns, we do not place any significant
weight to the imputation studies presented in this case. Many of
the questions raised in these proceedings regarding imputation
will be addressed in docket UM 351. In the meantime, our decision
to use bill and keep as an interim compensation mechanism will
avoid expensive and time consuming disputes regarding imputation
that would otherwise result from choosing a cash compensation
approach.
(d) The Commission disagrees with USWC's proposal to include
an I-USC in the interconnection charge. The I-USC is not required
to ensure that AECs contribute to universal service. Although
USWC raises a number of valid concerns, the Commission has
already established a method in docket UM 731 to fund universal
service in Oregon. On October 17, 1995, we issued Order No.
95-1103, approving an assessment on the intrastate gross revenues
of all authorized telecommunications providers. Phase II of that
docket is now underway to resolve issues relating to the specific
design and implementation of the universal service charge.
Furthermore, the applicants have stated that they will comply
with Commission imposed universal service requirements. Pursuant
to ORS 759.050(2)(c), compliance with such requirements shall be
a condition of the applicants' authority to provide local
service.
USWC's proposed I-USC has a number of other flaws that make it
unacceptable as a component of interconnection compensation. To
begin with, the I-USC is not based on the actual cost of
interconnection, but is intended to compensate USWC for lost
contribution that results when customers choose an AEC for
business service. USWC's calculation of the I-USC also assumes
that USWC will lose a business customer for every line obtained
by an AEC. As emphasized earlier in this order, the Commission
does not agree with the assumption that the local exchange market
is static. Rather, we expect that competition will cause local
service markets to expand, creating additional customer demand.
We also believe that LEC fears of substantial near term net
revenue loss are overstated. As MFS points out, it will likely
take several months for AECs to begin operations. Once they do,
the AECs will compete with incumbent carriers that now supply 100
percent of the local exchange market. This level of LEC market
dominance, together with the unavailability of database number
portability, should limit AEC market penetration for some time to
come.
A second problem with USWC's proposal is that it can collect
an I-USC for minutes terminated by customers who were never USWC
customers, but were former customers of another LEC. This is
clearly inappropriate, since it effectively creates a new revenue
source unrelated to USWC's objective of maintaining universal
service support. It is also inefficient, because USWC would have
no incentive to compete if it could receive contribution from a
customer even when it did not incur any cost to provide service.
USWC has also not quantified the level of support necessary to
fund universal service or indicated how the monies collected by
the I-USC would be used. In contrast to the universal service
support mechanism established in docket UM 731, there is no
assurance the I-USC would be administered in a manner that is
competitively neutral.
Finally, the criteria proposed by USWC for waiving the I-USC
are arbitrary and extremely difficult to enforce. They would
engender endless disputes over whether an AEC has sustained a
"comparable ratio of business to residential customers"
or whether it serves a "similar demographic and geographic
penetration." Such conditions have the effect of
discouraging competitive entry and are unnecessary given our
decision in the universal service docket.
(e) In addition to our concerns with the I-USC, we also
disagree with USWC's proposed interconnection charge. The
interconnection charge is a residually priced element designed to
recover revenues associated with USWC's proposed Local Transport
Restructure (LTR) filing. The Commission has not made a decision
on that filing.
(f) The Commission also finds that the one way compensation
approach recommended by Staff is not in the public interest.
Staff's attempt to achieve "regulatory symmetry" by
denying AECs compensation for interconnection would effectively
foreclose meaningful competition for local exchange service.
Although USWC and GTE have shouldered responsibility for
universal service to date, those obligations will be shared by
all telecommunications providers, pursuant to our decision in UM
731. The LECs continue to have responsibility for providing
ubiquitous service within their respective service territories,
but we are not convinced that COLR status is a liability for the
incumbents. As Mr. Montgomery points out, the ubiquitous provider
also possesses the opportunity to generate substantial revenues
by marketing vertical services to customers. Based on the
evidence presented, there is substantial reason to believe that
ubiquity may be an asset in a competitive environment.
While Staff asserts that AECs do not have the same regulatory
obligations as the LECs, it does not acknowledge the most
significant benefit associated with public utility status. As
regulated utilities, USWC and GTE are entitled to earn a
reasonable rate of return on all assets used to provide utility
service. If GTE believes its earnings are unreasonable, it may
request a rate increase from the Commission. It may also qualify
for interim rate relief under certain circumstances. USWC may
also seek regulatory relief if its return falls below below the
minimum level specified in its AFOR plan. Competitive providers
do not have these options and must rely entirely on their
performance in the marketplace.
We also disagree with Staff's attempt to compare AEC
operations with those of other providers. We are persuaded that
the facilities based services proposed by the applicants are
differently situated than the RCCs, STS, and other providers
mentioned by Staff. Likewise, we cannot find that the existing
RCC compensation structure supports Staff's claim that
nonreciprocal compensation will allow AECs to compete effectively
in the local exchange market. Instead, we are inclined to agree
with Dr. Cornell that nonreciprocal compensation is one reason
why cellular service is not perceived by the market as a
substitute for local dial tone service.
(g) We decline to adopt the flat rate proposal recommended by
TCG. There is insufficient evidence in the record to allow us to
determine whether the input assumptions used in calculating the
tandem port charge are reasonable. For example, we cannot tell
whether the estimated DS1 trunk usage of 216,000 minutes per
month is a reasonable approximation of actual usage. Second, we
are reluctant to adopt flat rate charges without a more complete
understanding of how such an approach corresponds with the cost
methodology adopted in Phase I of docket UM 351.
Also, because TCG's proposal is designed to encourage end
office terminations, it may skew AEC network architecture
decisions. There may be circumstances where it is more efficient
for an AEC to use tandem switching. We agree with MCImetro that
the Commission should not presume that one type of network
architecture is superior to another. Instead, the market should
determine how networks are constructed to meet customer needs.
Although we do not adopt TCG's proposal, we believe that flat
rate charges warrant further investigation. Based on our
understanding of how interconnection costs are incurred, some
type of flat rate structure may provide a reasonable basis for
compensating carriers. We also agree with Dr. Teske that flat
rate carrier compensation arrangements may be more compatible
with the flat rate retail pricing environment in Oregon than the
usage sensitive proposals offered in this case. In addition, flat
rate charges may be simpler and less costly to administer than
usage based methods.
Issue IV(f)(1): What arrangements are necessary to
accommodate existing extended area service (EAS) routes?
Positions of the Parties
ELI, MFS, MCImetro and TCG recommend that new
entrants should be allowed to establish EAS routes with incumbent
LECs on the same terms and conditions as exist over those routes
between incumbent LECs. These parties contend that there is no
justification for treating AECs differently from LECs and ILECs.
EAS routes were established to reflect communities of interest,
which do not change when a customer elects to receive service
from another carrier. MFS maintains that it would be
discriminatory to require AECs to pay higher rates than LECs for
the exchange of EAS traffic. MCImetro contends that requiring
AECs to pay switched access charges for EAS traffic would only
increase the overall price floor for local exchange services,
contrary to the public interest.
AT&T, OCTA, ELI, MFS, and TCG filed joint
recommendations stating that applicants will adopt existing local
exchange and EAS boundaries for purposes of intercompany
compensation.
Staff opposes bill and keep arrangements for EAS
traffic handled by AECs. It contends that current EAS
arrangements were designed for entities with similar regulatory
obligations. Also, the Commission's primary goal in establishing
EAS policy was to extend "local" dialing arrangements
between adjacent communities where a strong community of interest
exists, not to promote economic efficiency in a competitive
environment. Staff argues that its one way compensation proposal
should apply to traffic between AECs and LECs within and outside
the EAS regions.
Staff supports the comprehensive redesign of intercompany
network access charges proposed by USWC and GTE, because
competition will make access distinctions untenable in the long
run. As part of that redesign, Staff agrees that current bill and
keep arrangements for EAS traffic exchanged by incumbent LECs
should be eliminated. Such changes should not be made in these
dockets, however. The record is inadequate to assess the effect
of changes in access policy for IXCs, RCCs, and EAS-connecting
LECs. Staff recommends a separate EAS proceeding to investigate
revenue impacts and consider pricing issues.
GTE argues that this is not the proper forum to
integrate AECs into existing EAS arrangements. Since EAS is an
interexchange service and the only issue in this case is the
applicants' status as local exchange service providers, there is
no basis to establish the rates applicants should pay to
terminate their EAS-like traffic.
GTE further argues that existing EAS arrangements apply only to specific LECs and were designed to function only in a regulated monopoly environment. Further, current bill and keep arrangements for EAS traffic are merely an administrative detail. The purpose of EAS is to change end user toll billing, not to provide access charge discounts to interexchange service providers.
GTE also contends that LECs have given the Commission control
over their end user charges, and in return receive free
terminating access service for EAS traffic. Neither AECs nor IXCs
have made such a trade, and AECs should be excluded from the
existing EAS arrangements, just as IXCs are. GTE maintains that
applicants should pay the same access charges to terminate
interexchange traffic as IXCs now pay to terminate toll traffic.
Ultimately, the Commission must decide whether flat rate EAS is
viable in a competitive market.
Finally, GTE maintains that if the Commission approves an interconnection compensation arrangement for EAS-like traffic that is different than for toll traffic, then EAS-like traffic must be defined in the same manner for LECs and AECs. This poses no problem, because the AECs propose to operate in competitive zones that are coextensive with existing LEC exchange areas. But there may be a problem with defining toll calls for rating purposes. Specifically, while some of the applicants intend to define local and EAS-like traffic in a manner consistent with current industry practice, it is not clear that they intend to establish toll rating points consistent with current practices. If they do not, customer toll bills will be affected.
USWC also argues that the exchange of EAS traffic on a
bill and keep basis is premised on a monopoly environment, which
no longer exists. The policy reasons that led the Commission to
approve EAS must be reevaluated in a competitive environment.
Since all providers are potential competitors, the current
approach to EAS is not sustainable and must be converted to
interexchange access charges.
USWC acknowledges that it may not be possible to evaluate the
impact of competition on EAS in these dockets. Until the
Commission can consider an integrated approach to interconnection
and compensation, USWC proposes that USWC and the ILECs in the
Portland EAS region continue to exchange traffic between their
respective customers through the use of the existing bill and
keep EAS arrangements.
For traffic between AECs and ILECs within the Portland EAS
region, USWC proposes the following interim interconnection
arrangement: For traffic delivered by an AEC directly to USWC for
termination on ILEC facilities, USWC would charge the AEC tandem
switching, tandem switched transport, local switching, and the
I-USC. For traffic delivered by an ILEC to USWC for termination
on AEC facilities, USWC would pay the AEC its local switching
charge. During the interim, incumbent LECs would not be charged
for the portion of the traffic that transits each company's
respective EAS facilities. Existing compensation relationships
between USWC and the ILECs will remain unchanged.
OITA argues that the Commission should establish a
fully competitive local exchange market if the applications are
granted. The best way to do this is to adopt the model of the
competitive interexchange market, including explicit intercarrier
compensation. Bill and keep arrangements are only valid in an EAS
market with restricted competition.
OITA also argues that EAS is not the subject of these dockets
and should not be changed here. AECs should not be permitted to
participate in established EAS routes, because EAS is an
interexchange service and these applications relate to the
establishment of competitive zones, not interexchange authority.
Further, OITA states that the Portland EAS region is served by
seven LECs, only two of which are parties to these dockets. The
other LECs should also be parties to any docket that deals with
EAS issues.
OITA asserts that the AECs are free to structure flat rate
offerings to their customers within the EAS zones. They are not
required to adopt EAS rates imposed on the LECs and are not
restricted by existing EAS boundaries. Therefore, AECs do not
need EAS to compete.
OITA opposes USWC's recommendation that other LECs in the
Portland EAS region pay transport charges for traffic originated
by an ILEC and transferred by USWC to a point of interconnection
with an AEC. USWC's proposal would alter the current compensation
arrangements for EAS traffic between USWC and the other LECs in
the Portland EAS region to resemble the compensation arrangements
that USWC proposes for AECs. OITA claims that it is inappropriate
to modify EAS arrangements among LECs in these dockets.
Commission Findings and Decision-Issue IV(f)(1)
The Commission disagrees with OITA's claim that EAS issues should not be addressed in this proceeding because (a) these applications involve local exchange competition and EAS is an interexchange service; and (b) not all affected LECs are represented in this docket. In the policy order establishing EAS regions, Order
No. 89-815, UM 189, at 7, the Commission stated:
Flat rate EAS is a hybrid with elements of both local and toll
service. EAS is currently provided by local exchange carriers as
part of local exchange service, with seven-digit dialing, and
local service billing. Because EAS goes beyond local exchange
boundaries, however, it is not "local exchange tele-
communications service" under Oregon law.
It is appropriate to deal with EAS, as a hybrid service with
elements of local service, in the current dockets, for the
purpose of distinguishing between local and toll calling for
purposes of intercompany compensation.
OITA's second point, that some affected LECs are not
represented in this proceeding, is without merit. OITA is an
organization that represents those ILECs. Moreover, all LECs had
notice of this docket, with the list of issues including the EAS
issue. If any LECs did not participate in these dockets, their
decision was an informed one.
The Commission disagrees that current EAS arrangements are
specific to incumbent LECs and that the AECs should pay switched
access charges and subsidies similar to those that IXCs now pay
to originate and terminate long distance traffic. Under the
proposals made by OITA, USWC, GTE and Staff, calls between
exchanges that would otherwise qualify as EAS traffic would
instead be toll calls if they originate from a new entrant's
customer. We see no justification for treating incumbent LECs and
AECs differently for EAS purposes. Since we have decided to adopt
bill and keep as an interim compensation method for intraexchange
traffic, it would be illogical to impose a different form of
compensation for EAS traffic. Moreover, current EAS routes are
established based on criteria that consider community of interest
calling areas. In the case of AECs, calls between exchanges
reflect customer calling areas of interest between two
neighboring exchanges just as if calls were handled by the
incumbent LECs. The identity of the companies involved is
irrelevant. The proposal to treat LECs and AECs differently
within the EAS region could severely disadvantage the new
entrants and hamper competition.
Furthermore, if the entrants are required to pay switched access charges for traffic that would otherwise be EAS traffic, it creates a windfall for the incumbents. The cost of turning the affected routes into local as opposed to toll routes is financed by the EAS surcharge. If such traffic is originated by an incumbent, no access revenues are currently received. No revenues should be generated just because an entrant originates the call.
Until otherwise ordered by the Commission, existing local
exchange boundaries and EAS routes shall apply to AECs as well as
incumbents for the purpose of distinguishing between local and
toll calling and for intercompany compensation. Thus, traffic
originated by any authorized local carrier that crosses exchange
boundaries within the Portland EAS region shall be treated as a
local call. In other words, if an LEC or AEC originates a call
that is terminated by another carrier within the EAS region,
compensation shall be on a bill and keep basis. Finally, if
USWC's or GTE's networks are used to transit calls between an
AEC's network and an ILEC's network within the Portland EAS
region, USWC or GTE must hand off the call on the same terms and
conditions as a call originating on their own networks.
With respect to GTE's concern about toll rating, AECs shall
limit each of their NXX codes to a given exchange and establish
rate centers in those exchanges that are proximate to the
existing LEC rate centers.
In reaching this decision, we recognize that EAS regions were
created in a regulated monopoly environment. That environment is
changing rapidly. As a number of parties have emphasized, it will
be necessary to reexamine EAS as competition expands. The
continued viability of existing EAS arrangements should be
examined by the work group established to investigate
interconnection compensation. As part of that process, the work
group shall consider the impact on rates and policy that may
result from the transition from existing bill and keep
arrangements to an interconnection compensation mechanism based
on reciprocal payments.
Issue IV(g): Is the applicants' proposed service compatible
with the existing network configuration and other requirements
associated with providing enhanced 911 (E-911) service?
Positions of the Parties
Staff believes that the AECs will use equipment that is
commonly used in the telecommunications industry. Assuming that
the AECs use acceptable engineering and design methods, Staff
expects no technical problems regarding the routing of the AECs'
E-911 traffic to the USWC selective routing tandem switch and
ultimately to the appropriate public safety answering point
(PSAP).
ELI states that its proposed service is compatible with
the existing network configuration and other requirements
associated with providing E-911 service. ELI needs the incumbent
LECs to route E-911 calls from subscribers to direct inward
dialed numbers as well as the ELI NXX (972). To expedite E-911
capability, ELI will purchase E-911 trunks and database services
from existing 911 interconnection tariffs. When formal agreements
are drafted between USWC and ELI for other ancillary services,
ELI will negotiate E-911 agreements with the relevant
governmental authority and the incumbent LEC just as ILECs do.
MFS also states that its services will be compatible
with the existing network configuration in Oregon and will meet
the requirements associated with providing E-911 service. It will
have the capability to complete calls to 911 emergency services
and will coordinate with the agency operating the PSAP in each
locality that MFS serves, to assure that 911 calls are routed and
delivered in the manner desired by the PSAP. Where E-911 service
has been implemented, MFS will also make arrangements for the
proper delivery of Automatic Number Identification and Automatic
Location Identification (ALI) information to the PSAP. As one of
its co-carrier arrangements, MFS requests that USWC and GTE be
required to provide trunk connections to their 911 tandems and to
cooperate in loading ALI and other routing information into
databases.
MCImetro agrees to work with the LECs and the emergency
service agencies to make the necessary arrangements for
compatibility.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue IV(g)
There is a reasonable basis to conclude that the service
proposed by the applicants will be compatible with the existing
network configuration and other requirements associated with
providing E-911 service. The applicants have primary
responsibility to work with the E-911 agencies to make certain
that all users of their services have access to the emergency
system.
Issue IV(h): What interconnection arrangements between the applicants and LEC should be provided?
(1)What should be the conditions of such arrangements?
(2)What technical issues must be resolved?
Positions of the Parties: Physical
Interconnection Issues
ELI, MFS, AT&T, TCG and OCTA filed joint
recommendations requesting that LECs and AECs interconnect their
facilities at mutually agreed upon meet points. If parties do not
agree upon a meet point within 45 days, either may seek
appropriate and immediate relief from the Commission.
The signatories to the joint recommendations and MCImetro contend
that AECs should be allowed to interconnect with LECs for the
mutual exchange of local and EAS traffic under the same
interconnection arrangements used by incumbent LECs. LEC networks
are interconnected using two way dedicated trunks at mutually
agreed meet points. Each carrier is responsible for building and
maintaining its own facilities up to the meet point and for
maintaining common technical specifications at the meet point. In
addition, each carrier is responsible for traffic originating on
its network up to the meet point and for terminating the traffic
handed off from another carrier at the meet point.
ELI opposes USWC's recommendation that interconnection
occur just outside the central office of the carrier originating
the call. Under that proposal, all interconnection would fall
under USWC's Virtual Expanded Interconnection Tariff. ELI
contends that USWC's proposal is inefficient and discriminatory,
particularly since USWC does not propose modifying existing meet
point interconnection arrangements with ILECs. ELI states that
there are no unresolved technical issues regarding the
interconnection of LEC and AEC networks.
MFS states that there must be a common set of standards
to permit physical interconnection of carrier networks. Since
USWC and GTE already interconnect with a variety of other
carriers, the Commission need not specify the actual terms of
interconnection. Instead, AECs should be permitted to designate
interconnection meet points so that network economies can be
achieved. By limiting interconnection to LEC end offices,
existing network inefficiencies will be imposed on AECs. If
implementation issues arise, AECs should be allowed to seek
relief from the Commission.
TCG contends that the most efficient and economical
interconnection between LECs and AECs is to use two way DS1
trunks with full Feature Group D characteristics and SS7
capabilities. Using one way or multiple traffic specific trunks
requires additional facilities, which necessarily increases the
cost of interconnection. Likewise, it depletes switch capacity by
requiring additional ports and imposes costs to prematurely
upgrade and expand switch capacity.
TCG also recommends that the location of interconnection facilities should be determined by good faith negotiations between interconnecting parties. The aim of such negotiations should be to equalize the costs and benefits to both parties in selecting and constructing interconnection points. In order to equalize the bargaining power of the parties and create an incentive for the most efficient interconnection, the Commission should require equal sharing of all costs associated with the construction of facilities. TCG stresses that it is inappropriate to allow LECs to unilaterally designate interconnection meet points, since the LECs have an incentive to select locations that will disadvantage the AECs.
Staff states that interconnection between the AECs and
LECs should use the same technical methods now used by LECs to
interconnect their networks. If all carriers use the same
procedures, protocols, and equipment designed for the existing
telephone network, no technical problems should arise. The only
condition of interconnection should be that applicants not take
any action that impairs the ability of the incumbent LECs to meet
the service standards specified by the Commission. With
interconnected networks, all carriers must cooperate to maintain
uninterrupted operation of the combined network.
USWC states that competitive entry by facilities based
telecommunications providers will not create technical
interconnection issues. In a competitive environment,
interconnecting carriers must be able to extend their facilities
to the end offices of other providers if they choose, and not be
forced to use the facilities of any other provider. Tandem
interconnection should also be available. Virtual collocation and
expanded interconnection should be offered by all carriers so
that interconnection is efficient. Providers should work out
mutual arrangements and based on what makes sense in any given
circumstance. LECs have negotiated interconnection arrangements
for many years and there is no reason to assume the same process
will not work with the AECs.
Regarding the location of interconnection facilities, USWC
proposes that the carrier originating a call should have the
right to establish the interconnection point between the
networks. USWC is willing to offer AECs the option of using
USWC's transport network to interconnect the AEC switch with
other local exchange carriers within the same LATA. USWC
currently provides the same functionality for traffic exchanged
between IXCs and independent telephone companies. USWC opposes
using meet point arrangements, because establishing meet points
in the middle of the transport line between the parties'
respective switches would result in an unacceptable level of meet
points scattered randomly throughout the Portland metropolitan
area.
GTE does not believe that the technical aspects of
interconnection will be problematic and assumes that the parties
will negotiate in good faith to establish mutually agreeable
arrangements. Once connections are established, GTE and
applicants must negotiate a billing process that will enable the
carrier terminating a call to bill applicable charges for local,
EAS, and toll calls. Second, if compensation differs between
types of traffic, then separate trunk groups will need to be
established for each type of traffic in accordance with current
industry practice.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(h) Physical Interconnection
Consistent with our decision that AECs should be treated as
co-carriers, the Commission finds that the applicants should be
permitted to interconnect with incumbent providers on the same
terms and conditions that LECs have used to interconnect their
telecommunications networks. This process contemplates that the
interconnecting parties will negotiate mutually acceptable
locations where network facilities can be joined. In some cases,
carriers will decide that the most efficient connection will be
at the end office of one of the carriers. In others, it may be
more convenient and less costly to establish meet points to
connect network facilities. Because these decisions will vary on
a case by case basis, the parties are in the best position to
determine the manner in which interconnection should take place.
We also agree with TCG that the parties will bargain on more
equal terms and have a greater incentive to agree upon the most
efficient interconnection if all costs associated with the
construction of facilities are shared equally.
The Commission declines to adopt recommendations that would
give either the LECs or the AECs the power to unilaterally
designate interconnection meet points. In a competitive
environment, carriers should not have an opportunity to select
interconnection locations that may disadvantage competing
providers.
The parties appear to agree that there are no significant
technical obstacles to interconnection, provided the AECs follow
existing protocols and procedures and install equipment that
complies with network standards. Since the applicants have
indicated that they intend to abide by such requirements, we have
no reason to believe that technical problems will occur. We
concur with Staff that the applicants shall not take any action
that impairs the ability of the incumbent LECs to meet the
service standards specified by the Commission.
GTE's concern regarding trunking arrangements for AEC traffic
should be handled in the same manner that such issues are now
handled among incumbent providers. Since we have determined that
carriers should be compensated for local and EAS traffic using
the bill and keep arrangements currently in place for incumbent
providers, we presume that similar trunking arrangements are also
appropriate.
The Commission anticipates that USWC, GTE and the applicants
will negotiate in good faith and will establish mutually
acceptable interconnection arrangements in the vast majority of
cases. Where parties are unable to agree, they should notify the
Commission within three days. We will then take the steps
necessary to resolve the dispute on an expedited basis.
Unbundling and Resale Issues
Most of the parties agreed with or did not oppose the
provision in the Partial Stipulation that NAC unbundling would be
addressed in docket UM 351 rather than in the present docket.
Although we adopted this provision of the Partial Stipulation, a
number of parties request interim unbundling in these dockets.
Positions of the Parties
ELI, MFS, AT&T, TCG, and OCTA submitted
joint recommendations requesting that USWC and GTE be required to
file interim tariffs offering (a) local loops unbundled from
switching, channel termination, and channel performance at the
prices currently in effect for two wire private line NACs; and
(b) NAC connection at the TSLRIC specified in the UM 351 Phase I
cost report.
ELI claims that AECs need immediate access to unbundled
loops to bring the benefits of local exchange competition to
customers throughout Oregon. Without unbundling, competition will
proceed to rural areas and residential customers much more
slowly, if at all. ELI faces substantial economic barriers to
expanding its network to serve certain geographical locations and
to extend its advanced services to other customer groups.
Requiring unbundled loops on an interim basis is consistent with
Order No. 94-1851, which recognized that there might be a need
for interim relief pending the outcome of docket UM 351.
MFS concurs that failure to unbundle the local loop
will substantially circumscribe the development of local exchange
competition. It observes that the incumbent LECs have virtually
ubiquitous loops that provide access to every interexchange
carrier and virtually all residential and business premises in
their territory. Incumbent LECs have had the protection of their
monopoly status in building their networks, plus the advantage of
favorable franchises, access to rights of way, unique tax
treatment, access to buildings on an unpaid basis, and protection
against competition. AECs do not share in these advantages, and
it would be cost prohibitive and economically inefficient in most
cases for them to construct duplicate loop facilities. Moreover,
competitors cannot obtain public and private rights of way,
franchises, or building access on the same terms that incumbent
LECs enjoyed. Without unbundled loops, AECs will not be able to
offer competitive service to most of the population in a given
area. Various regulatory commissions have concluded that
unbundling the loop is essential to local exchange competition
MFS also contends that the price of unbundled loops must bear
a reasonable relationship to the retail price charged by the
incumbent LEC for a business line. Unbundled loop rates should be
based on TSLRIC costs developed in docket UM 351. MFS requests
the Commission to specify that the combined cost of the unbundled
elements cannot exceed the bundled retail rate. Moreover, until
TSLRIC cost studies are complete, USWC and GTE should be required
to impute whatever rates they charge for unbundled loops into
their own retail rates. Also, the combination of unbundled loop
costs and other elements should not exceed total bundled loop
costs.
MCImetro requests the Commission to require that USWC
and GTE unbundle and make available for resale the 34 unbundled
functionalities, or building blocks, listed on MCImetro Exhibits
3 and 5. If these building blocks are available on an unbundled
basis, the new entrants will be able to provide a variety of
services they cannot otherwise economically afford to offer.
Unbundled loops, for example, are necessary to permit entrants to
offer local residential or business dial tone to customers not
located on the entrant's fiber optic ring. Removing restrictions
on resale is equally important to the provision of meaningful
local exchange service. Prices for unbundled functions should be
based on TSLRIC at a level which allows an LEC's comparable
bundled tariff rates to pass an imputation test, so that entrants
are not placed in a price squeeze. Resellers should be permitted
to bundle these services with auxiliary services of their own
choosing to bring the benefits of competition to Oregon
consumers.
MCImetro states that USWC's offer to sell retail private line
service to entrants in lieu of providing unbundled loops
effectively places the entrants in a price squeeze. MCImetro also
contends that USWC's definition of "essential
facilities" is contrary to the approach recently adopted by
the Commission in Order Nos. 94-1851 and 95-313.
AT&T contends that the LECs are refusing to
unbundle the local network in order to impede competition. This
refusal will force the new entrants to use inappropriate,
overpriced substitutes. It will also prevent new entrants from
developing their networks in the most efficient manner, by
preventing interconnection at all feasible points. Third, it will
prohibit innovation by preventing the new entrants from
developing creative, useful services using unbundled monopoly
elements. Finally, by refusing to permit commercially viable
resale of their services, the LECs will preclude consumers,
especially residential and rural customers, from enjoying the
benefits of competition as soon as possible.
AT&T acknowledges that unbundling will be addressed
comprehensively in docket UM 351. As indicated in Order No.
94-1851, however, the Commission should unbundle the local
network in a limited fashion in these proceedings by ordering
USWC and GTE to provide unbundled loops and ports immediately.
The availability of unbundled loops will allow new entrants to
expand their service areas more rapidly. Also, as Dr. Cornell
notes, by selling loops to new entrants the LECs will continue to
receive revenues, offsetting the loss of a customer. Finally,
consumers will benefit from having more choice.
TCG states that the Commission should order USWC and
GTE to unbundle and make available for resale subscriber loops
and line side interconnection as described in the joint
recommendations. The availability of these facilities at
imputable rates, terms, and conditions will enhance the AECs'
ability to expand their networks more rapidly, facilitating more
end office interconnection and provision of service to
residential and small business customers. AECs cannot construct
overnight the same network that LECs' have taken decades to
build.
USWC opposes the unbundling proposals submitted in this
proceeding. It maintains that the Commission lacks jurisdiction
to require a utility to make "bits and pieces" of its
facilities available to competitors under any circumstances. USWC
argues that none of its services are truly essential to
competitors as long as network interconnection is offered on
reasonable terms and conditions. It maintains that no facts have
been introduced to support the claim that loops and loop
components such as drops and feeder and distribution are
essential facilities.
USWC proposes to unbundle its switched access service by
implementing its LTR and expanded interconnection channel
termination proposals. This will allow interconnecting carriers
to use only the switching and transport services of USWC that
they desire. USWC expects the Commission will resolve unbundling
issues in the context of UM 351.
USWC states that resale would not be an issue if its rates
were set to cover cost and make a reasonable contribution, and
there were no artificial distinctions between classes of service.
But this is not the case. All services permitted to be resold
should be priced above ADSRC. Residential service should not be
resold as business service if it is priced differently in the
interests of universal service. Other carriers should not be able
to resell USWC exchange services bundled with their interLATA
long distance services until USWC is permitted to do the same.
Finally, other carriers should not be allowed to avoid the
payment of access charges by delivering traffic to USWC through
the resale of its exchange services.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(h) Unbundling and Resale
In Order No. 93-852, we adopted Open Network Architecture
rules in order to obtain efficient delivery of enhanced
telecommunications services to the public and achieve greater
competitive equity between providers of telecommunications
service. The rules require unbundling of telecommunications
services "to encourage the development of enhanced services
and provide for a more competitive enhanced services
market." OAR 860-35-030(1). Without unbundling and the
eventual removal of resale restrictions, competition will proceed
to rural and residential customers slowly, if at all. New local
exchange providers face substantial economic barriers to
expanding their networks to serve certain geographical locations
and providing advanced services to residential customers.
Constructing new facilities is a capital intensive, time
consuming process. In the near future, the new entrants cannot be
expected to duplicate the extensive networks maintained by the
LECs. Unbundling and resale of telecommunications services will
hasten the arrival of effective competition in Oregon.
As noted elsewhere in this order, the Commission is in the
final stages of docket UM 351, a comprehensive investigation of
unbundling and pricing issues. Evidentiary hearings have
concluded in that proceeding and an order is expected shortly. In
that proceeding, the Commission will specify the level and extent
of unbundling that must occur to accommodate competition in
telecommunications markets. In addition, we will address issues
relating to existing use and user restrictions and the resale of
telecommunications services. In view of these facts, we have
elected not to unbundle any telecommunications services or remove
any resale restrictions in these dockets.
Issue IV(i): What arrangements are necessary for the
assignment of telephone numbers to the applicants?
The assignment of telephone numbers is administered by the
North American Numbering Plan Administrator, who assigns
Numbering Plan Area (NPA) codes and Service Area Codes (SAC). The
NPAs are assigned to Area Code Administrators, who assign the
prefixes (NXX codes) to carriers. The combination of the NPA and
the NXX identifies a specific carrier's central office, which
serves a specific geographical area. The last four digits
identify a specific line appearance on a switch to which the end
user is connected (e.g., 503-223-9999). SACs are assigned to
carriers to provide services such as 800, 700, etc. These numbers
are aliases for geographic numbers and must be translated into
geographic numbers before a call can be completed.
Geographic numbers are assigned only to carriers who provide
wireline or cellular telephone service in the Public Switched
Telephone Network. They are assigned according to the Central
Office Code Assignment Guidelines (ICCF 93-00729-010) developed
by the Industry Numbering Committee. Before a carrier can obtain
prefixes, it must prove that it is authorized to provide service.
Positions of the Parties
USWC, as numbering plan administrator for Oregon, is
responsible for assigning central office codes to AECs. USWC
assigns codes in accordance with the industry's Central Office
Code Assignment Guidelines, which assures that AECs will have
equitable access to central office code assignments. ELI has
already been assigned the central office code 972 for Portland.
GTE agrees that procedures are already in place for
assigning telephone numbers, and that, once authorized, the
applicants need only request numbering resources from USWC, the
plan administrator.
Staff, MCImetro, MFS, Sprint, and TCG recommend
that USWC assign numbering resources to the applicants according
to normal guidelines in a nondiscriminatory manner.
AT&T expresses concern that the LECs may give
themselves preference in providing and administering numbers
because the incumbents currently control number assignment and
administration. It recommends that the Commission order USWC to
administer numbers on a competitively neutral basis. Eventually,
the only way to ensure evenhanded allocation of numbering
resources among competing vendors is to vest control of numbering
resources and administration in an impartial third party.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(i)
AECs cannot compete in the local exchange market unless they
have nondiscriminatory access to numbering resources. As
co-carriers, AECs are entitled to receive central office code
assignments according to the same rates, terms, and conditions as
any RBOC or LEC. Guidelines for the assignment of numbers are in
place, and ELI has already received the 972 prefix for the
Portland area. USWC shall apply existing guidelines for assigning
numbers to the AECs in a nondiscriminatory manner.
Issue IV(j): What arrangements are necessary to ensure
adequate number portability?
Under the North American Numbering Plan, LECs receive blocks
of telephone numbers, which are assigned to a given switch or
serving wire center served by a switch. Traditionally, customers
moving outside the area served by a switch must relinquish their
telephone numbers and receive new numbers from the new serving
switch. This is the case regardless of whether the new switch is
operated by the incumbent LEC or an AEC.
Number portability allows customers to retain their telephone
numbers even when served by a different switch or local service
provider. There are two general types of number portability.
Service provider number portability permits customers to keep
their telephone numbers if they change local service providers.
Geographic number portability, on the other hand, allows
customers to move from one location to another without changing
telephone numbers. As the geographic area associated with number
portability expands, implementation issues become significantly
more complex.
Positions of the Parties
Applicants and several intervenors argue that
number portability is essential to local exchange competition.
Market studies conducted by MFS indicate that most customers are
reluctant to change telephone carriers if they are also required
to change telephone numbers at the same time. Customers consider
changing telephone numbers both an inconvenience and an expense.
Telephone numbers are given out to a wide variety of individuals,
and are stored in computer databases, fax machines, modems and
personal files. Businesses are generally required to print new
stationery and business cards and send mailings to customers and
vendors notifying them of the new number. Smaller businesses
often invest substantial amounts of money in advertising their
telephone number. Some rely on incoming calls as the primary
source of sales.
TCG points out that number portability is necessary to
achieve traffic balance between LECs and AECs. Without number
portability, customers with predominantly inbound usage are
likely to remain with the LEC rather than change telephone
numbers. Customers with predominantly outbound usage, on the
other hand, are not similarly handicapped by the lack of
portability. AECs will thus be relegated to serving customers
with primarily outbound usage and will terminate the vast
majority of that traffic on LEC networks.
USWC takes the position that number portability is not
essential for AECs to compete for local exchange traffic.
According to USWC witness Purkey, the new prefixes assigned to
AECs will allow them to offer hundreds of "good
numbers" to their customers. So while it may be desirable
for a customer to retain an existing telephone number, it is not
essential to local exchange competition.
Database Number Portability. A long term
solution to service provider and geographic number portability
will require use of a centralized database and Advanced
Intelligent Network (AIN) capabilities incorporated in modern
switching technology. Although such a solution is not yet ready
for implementation, efforts are underway to resolve outstanding
technical, operational and administrative issues. Several of the
parties to this proceeding are participating in the Number
Portability Workshop convened by the Industry Numbering
Committee. Technical trials of three proposed database solutions
are also underway in other states.
GTE argues that database portability will be costly to
implement and may not generate sufficient customer demand to
warrant the expense. In the alternative, GTE suggests that
customers and AECs be assigned nongeographic "virtual"
numbers that operate similar to an "800" number and can
direct calls to a customer's current geographic number no matter
which local service provider originally assigned the number. GTE
witness Beauvais maintains that this approach is technologically
feasible, relatively cheap compared to other portability schemes,
and will function as an interim or permanent solution depending
on customer demand.
The parties also disagree over the timetable for implementing
database number portability. ELI and MCImetro state
that a solution is possible within 12-18 months, but assert that
incumbent LECs have no incentive to proceed with the development
of a database solution. They recommend that the Commission order
an investigation of different number portability approaches, and
require the LECs to submit a report within six months. USWC
and GTE, on the other hand, contend that a database
solution will not be available in the near term. USWC points out
that the FCC has initiated a new rulemaking docket to investigate
number portability, and suggests that it is premature to mandate
deployment of a specific database solution until other methods
can be fully evaluated.
Staff recommends against adopting a permanent number portability solution in this docket. Staff witness Harris asserts that requiring special number portability procedures would effectively impose an obligation on LECs to assist competitors. Staff states that the number portability solution ultimately adopted by the Commission should (a) include both service provider and geographic portability,
(b) be reciprocal among telecommunications providers; and (c)
not degrade access to emergency services. Staff further
recommends that the cost to develop, deploy and use number
portability should be born by those who use it.
As noted above, Item 4 of the Partial Stipulation submitted by
MFS, ELI, AT&T, Sprint, OCTA, TCG, OECA, and GTE
requested that the Commission open a docket by January 31, 1996,
to consider and resolve issues relating to database number
portability. The stipulation also requests that a work group be
created to monitor the progress and results of number portability
trials in other states.
Interim Portability. The parties
generally agree that, until a database solution is developed,
interim arrangements using existing technology can be employed to
provide service provider number portability.
USWC proposes to offer service provider portability
using Remote Call Forwarding (RCF) and Directory Number Route
Indexing (DNRI) at a price of approximately $4.00 per month. A
nonrecurring charge would apply to an AEC's initial establishment
of DNRI or RCF in each central office. A second nonrecurring
charge would apply to activation of each portable number.
GTE acknowledges that neither database portability or
its proposed virtual nongeographic method are currently
available. It is willing to consider alternative methods, such as
remote call forwarding, to provide interim portability. GTE
argues that the cost of portability arrangements should be borne
by those customers that demand the service.
Staff recommends that the Commission require USWC and
GTE to file tariffs offering RCF or DNRI to AECs as an interim
solution to number portability. Staff notes that existing tariff
rates may need to be changed in order to allow those services to
be resold by the applicants. USWC's version of remote call
forwarding, known as Market Expansion Line, is currently offered
at $16.00 per month. GTE offers a RCF service for $15.00 per
month. Staff proposes that USWC and GTE file cost support for
interim number portability tariffs within 60 days after an order
is issued in these proceedings.
ELI, MFS and TCG recommend that interim number
portability be implemented using remote call forwarding methods.
These methods - also referred
to as co-carrier call forwarding (CCF) - can be deployed quickly
and have fewer technical limitations than other interim
approaches. According to MFS witness Schulz, CCF eliminates
inefficient trunking arrangements by allowing forwarded calls to
be routed through the tandem switch over common trunk groups. It
also permits use of SS7 signaling capabilities. Technical
concerns associated with CCF and other interim number portability
solutions include: (a) the fact that all calls must be routed to
the LEC switch before being forwarded to AEC facilities,
resulting in additional transmission and switching expense, and
call setup time; and (b) most CLASS services cannot be provided.
ELI recommends that CCF interim number portability be included in
LEC local interconnection tariffs and offered to AECs at rates no
greater than TSLRIC. Pricing at this level reflects the technical
limitations inherent in interim portability arrangements and
mitigates the economic penalty imposed on AECs by the absence of
database number portability.
AT&T and MCImetro argue that all of the
proposed interim portability arrangements are seriously flawed
and no meaningful effort should be spent on improving them if
industry resources would otherwise be diverted from work on a
database solution. Aside from the problems mentioned above,
technical limitations associated with interim portability include
difficulty determining the source of service problems and the
proper attribution of access charges from interexchange carriers.
AT&T also states that interim arrangements should enable AECs
to interconnect at an access tandem rather than at every LEC end
office in which the AEC has customers. Interim arrangements
should also allow AECs to receive signaling information (e.g.,
calling party number) so that the AEC may offer its
"ported" customers the same complement of service
features that would otherwise be available from its switch.
MCImetro argues that number portability is
fundamentally a method of routing traffic and should be treated
as an interconnection service rather than an end user service. As
a result, interim portability should be priced below retail
rates. MCImetro proposes that the Commission follow the pricing
approach taken in New York or Michigan. The New York Public
Service Commission decision pools the cost of interim portability
arrangements and requires both LECs and AECs to pay a surcharge
on each telephone number. The underlying rationale is that all
consumers benefit from number portability because consumers
benefit from competition generally. In Michigan, the Public
Service Commission concluded that interim portability is an
essential service and should be offered to AECs at a price no
greater than economic cost.
ELI, MFS, AT&T, TCG and OCTA filed joint
recommendations requesting that the Commission require USWC and
GTE to file tariffs providing interim portability, including RCF
and DNRI, at a price equal to TSLRIC. Interim portability
arrangements should be offered on a bill and keep basis until
USWC and GTE file tariffs with appropriate cost support.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(j)
Based on the evidence presented, the Commission is persuaded
that number portability is an interconnection service that is
essential to the development of effective local exchange
competition. We agree with applicants that business and
residential customers have a substantial interest in retaining
their existing telephone numbers and are unlikely to change
service providers if forced to change those numbers.
Because number portability is necessary for competitive local
exchange markets to develop, it is important for the
telecommunications industry to produce a database solution as
soon as possible. At the same time, the Commission does not want
to take steps that duplicate or are inconsistent with efforts now
underway to arrive at a national solution to portability issues.
We therefore agree with the recommendation to establish a work
group to monitor developments in this area, including the results
of number portability trials in other states. The number
portability work group shall include the applicants, USWC, GTE,
Staff, and other interested parties, including consumer groups,
ILECs, and competitive providers. The work group shall submit
periodic reports evaluating the progress of database portability
trials and including recommendations regarding the timing and
implementation of a database number portability solution. The
first report shall be filed with the Commission no later than
July 1, 1996.
For the present, interim number portability should be offered
by allowing AECs to use RCF or DNRI technology. The evidence
indicates that these methods have a number of technical
limitations, but there appears to be general agreement that they
will function reasonably well as an interim solution.
From a pricing standpoint, we find that USWC and GTE should
file interim number portability tariffs offering both the RCF and
DNRI functions at a price equal to TSLRIC. Tariffs for RCF and
DNRI should be filed with the Commission no later than 30 days
from the date of this order. The tariffs filed by GTE and USWC
may include a nonrecurring service provisioning charge, which
should also be set at cost. The interim number portability rates
prescribed in this order should remain in effect until such time
as the Commission concludes its most recent cost investigation in
docket UM 773. Based on the results of that investigation, we may
modify the rate adopted in these proceedings. The rate for
interim number portability may also be adjusted as a result of
the unbundling and pricing investigation in docket UM 351 and/or
subsequent rate proceedings for USWC and GTE.
USWC and GTE will not be adversely affected if interim number
portability is offered to the applicants at TSLRIC. As noted
above, we expect that it will take several months for AECs to
begin operations, and an even longer period of time before they
are able to penetrate local exchange markets to any significant
extent. Demand for interim number portability should therefore
not be substantial in the near term. Also, because DNRI and RCF
are technically inferior methods of providing number portability,
it is reasonable to establish the initial price at economic cost.
The current tariff rates for remote call forwarding services, on
the other hand, would impose very high costs on the AECs and
effectively foreclose competitive entry. USWC did not file any
cost justification for its proposed $4.00 interim portability
rate.
Issue IV(k): If the applications are granted, should there
be any limits on the LEC pricing flexibility in ORS
759.050(5)(a)?
Subsection (5)(a) of ORS 759.050 provides:
unless the commission determines that it is not in the public
interest at the time a competitive zone is created, upon
designation of a competitive zone, price changes, service
variations, and modifications of competitive zone services
offered by a telecommunications utility in the zone shall not be
subject to [the notice, hearing and tariff suspension procedures
in] ORS 759.180 to ORS 759.190, and at the telecommunications
utility's discretion, such changes may be made effective upon
filing with the commission.
Subsection (5)(b) of ORS 759.050 further provides:
[t]he price and terms of service offered by a
telecommunications utility for a competitive zone service within
a competitive zone may differ from that outside of the zone.
However, the price for a competitive zone service within the zone
may not be lower than the total service long run incremental
cost, for nonessential functions, of providing the service within
the zone and the charges for essential functions used in
providing the service but the commission may establish rates for
residential local exchange telecommunications service at any
level necessary to achieve the commission's universal service
objectives. Within the zone, the price of a competitive zone
service or any essential function used in providing the
competitive zone service may not be higher than those prices in
effect when the competitive zone was established unless
authorized by the commission.
Subsection (5)(a) allows telecommunications utilities to
respond to competition within a competitive zone by authorizing
rate adjustments and implementation of new services without
regulatory intervention. Subsection (5)(b) discourages
anticompetitive pricing by imposing an imputation price floor on
all competitive zone services. It also prevents price gouging by
prescribing existing rates as the price cap for all essential
functions and competitive zone services.
Positions of the Parties
ELI argues that LEC pricing flexibility should be
limited until: (a) a certificate is issued to an AEC; (b) the AEC
begins providing telecommunications service within its authorized
geographic area; and (c) the incumbent LEC has provided the AEC
with all necessary forms of interconnection, including
interconnection to unbundled loops. ELI maintains that customers
within the competitive zone will not have a reasonable
alternative for local exchange service until such time as
interconnection arrangements are in place and there is a mutual
exchange of traffic. ELI asserts that granting LECs premature
pricing flexibility within the competitive zone will allow them
to lock in customers with special discounts and contractual
arrangements before the AECs have entered the market, thereby
retarding competition in a manner contrary to the public
interest.
ELI also argues that AECs must have access to unbundled loops
in order to compete for customers located within the competitive
zone but outside the scope of existing AEC facilities. Because
these loops are essential functions, LECs cannot satisfy
statutory imputation requirements if LECs have pricing
flexibility prior to the availability of unbundled loops.
According to ELI witness Robert McMillin, incumbent LECs will not
be materially disadvantaged by lack of pricing flexibility,
because AECs are foreclosed from effective market entry until
full interconnection and unbundled loops are available. Further,
LECs will still be able to enter into special contract
arrangements with those customers who do have a competitive
alternative.
MCImetro argues that the preconditions proposed by ELI
are necessary but not sufficient. It maintains that pricing
flexibility should be granted to LECs only when there is
effective competition in competitive zones or when pricing
flexibility in the competitive zones is not paid for by price
increases outside of the competitive zones. Dr. Cornell
emphasizes that incumbent LECs should not have the ability to
lower prices within the competitive zone and implement offsetting
increases to customers located outside the competitive zone.
MFS recommends that consideration of LEC pricing
flexibility should begin with the acknowledgment that the
incumbent provider commands virtually 100 percent market share,
has the potential to cross subsidize because of its captive
customer base, and, as a result, wields enormous market power
within its service territory. This situation is not changed by
the appearance of AECs, nor does it signal the presence of
effective competition. It also recommends that LECs not receive
pricing flexibility within the competitive zone until effective
competition exists.
TCG emphasizes that the substantial market power of
incumbent LECs requires that they be regulated with greater
scrutiny than AECs. LECs should be required to file cost
justified tariffs for all competitive services and adhere to the
imputation requirements in ORS 759.050(5)(b) for all competitive
service offerings.
GTE, Staff, AT&T, and Sprint do not advocate
placing limits on LEC pricing flexibility beyond those imposed by
statute. Sprint emphasizes that regulation of incumbent LECs
should be a function of market power and the extent to which the
LECs are able to leverage control of essential facilities. As
long as incumbent LECs possess substantially more market power
than new entrants, greater regulatory oversight is appropriate.
Sprint further argues that traditional rate base regulation
should eventually be replaced with price and service regulation
designed to provide appropriate incentives as local telephone
competition emerges.
USWC points out that it already possesses both upward
and downward pricing flexibility for nonessential services under
its AFOR plan. It urges that the upward pricing flexibility
permitted by the AFOR should not be restricted and disputes the
suggestion that it might use such flexibility to shift costs to
noncompetitive services. USWC witness Carl Inouye emphasizes that
if USWC decides to lower essential service prices within the
competitive zone, the only way to recover those revenues under
the AFOR is by raising rates for nonessential services. To date,
USWC has made little use of its limited upward pricing
flexibility and is more likely absorb a revenue shortfall than
increase prices. Moreover, to the extent that shifts in revenue
requirement responsibility occur in a competitive market, it is
incorrect to assume that such changes will result in a cross
subsidy or other inappropriate policy result.
USWC maintains that LECs should also receive the downward
pricing flexibility contemplated by ORS 759.050(5). Since
essential service rates are effectively frozen under the AFOR,
downward flexibility within the competitive zone will benefit
USWC's essential service customers. USWC emphasizes that the
imputation requirement in the statute effectively precludes any
possibility that LECs will cross subsidize services. In addition,
USWC challenges the argument that LEC pricing flexibility should
be withheld until effective competition exists. Mr. Inouye notes
that such a requirement is not imposed by ORS 759.050 and is
illogical in any event, since there is no possibility of
effective competition if LECs cannot respond to AEC market
initiatives. USWC points out that the Commission rejected the
notion that effective competition must be present when it
approved the existing AFOR plan.
With respect to the incentives created by traditional
regulatory processes, USWC intends to propose price regulation as
an alternative regulatory framework when the AFOR expires in
1996. USWC contemplates that rate rebalancing, including rate
deaveraging and the elimination of internal subsidies, will be an
issue in the rate trueup process in that docket.
Commission Findings and Decision: Issue
IV(k)
The Commission finds that USWC and GTE should receive pricing
flexibility under ORS 759.050(5) once: (a) applicants have
received certificates of authority to provide local exchange
service consistent with the terms of this order; (b) the
Commission approves the tariffs filed by USWC and GTE in
compliance with this order; and (c) Staff notifies the
Commission that interconnection arrangements are in place and a
mutual exchange of traffic exists between GTE and USWC and an
authorized AEC. These conditions will ensure that there is a
competitive alternative in the local market at the time USWC and
GTE receive the pricing flexibility contemplated by ORS 759.050.
We also find that the pricing flexibility authorized in USWC's AFOR should not be restricted. No evidence has been presented to show that USWC has engaged in anticompetitive pricing or otherwise abused its authority to price list nonessential services during the four years the AFOR has been in effect. ORS 759.195(7) and
ORS 756.500 provide adequate procedural remedies for any
customer who alleges that USWC's pricing decisions are
unreasonable.
We do not agree with MCImetro and MFS that LEC pricing
flexibility should be withheld until effective competition
exists. ORS 759.050(2)(b) provides that "price and service
competition . . .shall not be deemed to exist by virtue of the
establishment of a competitive zone." While the Commission
could impose such a requirement as a condition to creating
competitive zones, we do not believe that it is necessary to
protect customers or foster competition in local exchange
markets. In our opinion, the imputation price floor prescribed in
the competitive zone statute effectively precludes the potential
for cross subsidy and other forms of anticompetitive pricing.
Moreover, USWC already exercises pricing flexibility under its
AFOR plan without any discernible adverse effects. As an
additional safeguard, ORS 759.050(7) provides that any
telecommunications provider or customer aggrieved by the prices,
terms of service or practices of another provider may file a
complaint with the Commission under ORS 756.500.
The Commission is also not persuaded by ELI's argument that
LEC loops must be unbundled prior to granting LECs the pricing
flexibility contemplated by the competitive zone statute. As we
have emphasized, access to unbundled LEC loops is being examined
as part of the comprehensive unbundling and repricing
investigation in docket UM 351, Phase II. The order issued in
that docket will specify the level and extent of unbundling of
LEC services necessary to permit effective competition in Oregon
telecommunications markets.
ORS 759.050(5)(d) provides that the Commission may order a
telecommunications utility to disaggregate and offer essential
functions of the utility's local exchange network. Our decision
to authorize pricing flexibility for USWC and GTE in the
competitive zones is predicated on the assumption that those LECs
will comply with the unbundling decisions that we make in docket
UM 351. Failure to comply with our unbundling determinations will
require us to reconsider the decision that pricing flexibility is
in the public interest.
The Commission has reviewed the record in these dockets in
light of the factors required by ORS 759.050(2)(a). On
consideration of those factors, the Commission concludes that it
is in the public interest to grant the applications of Electric
Lightwave, Inc., MFS Intelenet of Oregon, Inc., and MCI Metro
Access Transmission Services, Inc., for authority to provide
local telecommunications services in Oregon. The following USWC
exchanges should be designated as competitive zones under the
statute: Burlington, Lake Oswego, Milwaukie, North Plains, Oak
Grove, Oregon City, and Portland. In addition, the following GTE
exchanges shall be designated as competitive zones: Beaverton,
Forest Grove, Gresham, Hillsboro, Scholls, Sherwood, Stafford,
and Tigard.
IT IS ORDERED that:
1. The applications of Electric Lightwave, Inc., MFS Intelenet
of Oregon, Inc., and MCI Metro Access Transmission Services,
Inc., to provide local exchange telecommunications services in
the service areas of USWC and GTE are in the public interest and
are granted.
2. The following USWC exchanges are designated as competitive
zones: Burlington, Lake Oswego, Milwaukie, North Plains, Oak
Grove, Oregon City, and Portland.
3. The following GTE exchanges are designated as competitive
zones: Beaverton, Forest Grove, Gresham, Hillsboro, Scholls,
Sherwood, Stafford, and Tigard.
4. GTE and USWC shall offer ancillary services to the
applicants as agreed in the Stipulation and set forth in this
order. The applicants shall fulfill the conditions for 911
service stated in the Stipulation.
5. The applicants shall offer Enhanced 911 service as described in this
order.
6. Compensation for the exchange of local and EAS traffic
between the applicants and the LECs in the competitive zones
shall be based on bill and keep arrangements for a period of not
more than 24 months.
7. An industry work group shall be created to address interconnection compensation issues as described in this order.
a. The task of the work group shall be to formulate proposals for implementing a reciprocal interconnection rate structure applicable to all switched telecommunications traffic.
b. The interconnection compensation work group shall evaluate
the need for reciprocal payments in a competitive environment
that includes facilities based carriers as well as other types of
telecommunication service providers.
c. The interconnection compensation work group shall examine
the continued viability of existing EAS arrangements. The work
group should consider the impact on rates and policy from the
transition from bill and keep to interconnection compensation
based on reciprocal payments.
d. Staff shall submit reports to the Commission every six
months detailing the progress of the interconnection compensation
work group.
e. The applicants, USWC and GTE shall conduct and submit periodic traffic studies of local and EAS traffic exchanged with other carriers. The first study shall be submitted within six months of the date of this order. Additional studies shall be submitted every six months thereafter.
8. Existing local exchange boundaries and EAS routes
established by the Commission shall apply to AECs as well as
incumbents for the purpose of distinguishing between local and
toll calling and for intercompany compensation, until otherwise
ordered. AECs shall limit each of their NXX codes to a given
exchange and establish rate centers in those exchanges that are
proximate to existing LEC rate centers.
9. The applicants shall be permitted to interconnect with
incumbent providers on the same terms and conditions that LECs
have used to interconnect their telecommunications networks.
Applicants shall not take any action that impairs the ability of
the incumbent LECs to meet the service standards specified by the
Commission.
10. USWC shall apply existing guidelines for assigning numbers
to the AECs in a nondiscriminatory manner.
11. A work group shall be established to monitor database number portability issues, including the results of number portability trials in other states.
a. The work group shall include the applicants, USWC, GTE,
Staff, and other interested parties, including consumer groups, ILECs and competitive providers.
b. The work group shall submit periodic reports evaluating the
progress of database portability trials and including
recommendations regarding the timing and implementation of a
database number portability solution. The first report shall be
filed with the Commission no later than July 1, 1996.
12. Interim number portability shall be offered by allowing
AECs to use RCF or DNRI technology. USWC and GTE shall file
tariffs within 30 days from the date of this order offering both
the RCF and DNRI functions at a price equal to TSLRIC. The
tariffs may include a nonrecurring service provisioning charge,
which should also be set at cost.
13. USWC and GTE shall receive pricing flexibility under
ORS 759.050(5) once (a) applicants have received certificates
of authority to provide local exchange service consistent with
the terms of this order; (b) the Commission approves the tariffs
filed by USWC and GTE in compliance with this order; and
(c) Staff notifies the Commission that interconnection
arrangements are in place and a mutual exchange of traffic exists
between GTE and USWC and an authorized AEC.
14. Pursuant to ORS 759.050(2)(c), the applicants shall comply
with Commission imposed universal service requirements as a
condition of authority to provide local exchange service.
Made, entered, and effective ________________________.
______________________________ Roger Hamilton Chairman |
____________________________ Ron Eachus Commissioner |
____________________________ Joan H. Smith Commissioner |
A party may request rehearing or reconsideration of this order
pursuant to ORS 756.561. A request for rehearing or
reconsideration must be filed with the Commission within 60 days
of the date of service of this order. The request must comply
with the requirements in OAR 860-14-095. A copy of any such
request must also be served on each party to the proceeding as
provided by OAR 860-13-070(2). A party may appeal this order to a
court pursuant to ORS 756.580.
i:\cporder\order.doc
THE APPLICATIONS
CP 1: ELECTRIC LIGHTWAVE, INC..
On November 14, 1994, Electric Lightwave, Inc. (ELI) filed an
application with the Commission for certification to provide
telecommunications service in Oregon as a competitive provider.
ELI's application seeks authority to provide intraexchange
switched services. Initially, ELI intends to offer services
targeted to the business customer market within the ELI service
territory as defined below. These services will include, but not
be limited to, Centrex-type services, circuit-switched data
services, standard business line services, private branch
exchange (PBX) trunks, digital switched services, and ISDN
services. Other intraexchange switched services, including
residential service offerings, may be provided in the future. ELI
also seeks authority to provide all intrastate intraexchange
services incidental, supplementary, or related to any of the
foregoing.
ELI seeks authority to provide intraexchange switched service
in areas coextensive with the following local exchange areas:
Lake Oswego, Milwaukie-Oak Grove, Oregon City, and Portland (USWC
exchanges); and Beaverton, Gresham, Hillsboro, Sherwood,
Stafford, and Tigard (GTE exchanges).
Functionally equivalent or substitute intraexchange switched
services are readily available in the ELI service territory from
incumbent carriers including USWC and GTE. In addition,
substitute or alternative services are also available from
Centrex Resellers such as Enhanced Telemanagement Inc. (ET) and
shared tenant service providers.
ELI currently owns, controls, and operates a digital fiber
optic Metropolitan Area Network (MAN) in the Portland, Oregon
metropolitan area. The network is comprised of 134 miles of
96-strand, single mode fiber optic cable in place or under
construction, with an additional 200 miles in various stages of
engineering. ELI also has a primary network hub located in
downtown Portland. That hub contains a Northern Telecom DMS
100-200 switch with a DMS Supernode SE 60 processor. ELI seeks to
establish meet points and interconnect with incumbent LECs'
networks at various points, including end office switches, EAS
tandems, intraLATA toll tandems, interexchange carrier access
tandems, and operator services tandems. It will also request
transport facilities from LECs to transport ELI services to
remote locations. Transport facilities will include both analog
and digital transmission media. The traffic will be handed to
LECs at respective meet points and will be terminated at either
the customer premise, other carrier locations, or other ELI/LEC
meet points. ELI also will request ancillary services from LECs,
including 911 routing, directory assistance, number portability,
CLASS services, and operator services.
ELI is prepared to meet LECs in a timely fashion with a
circuit interface that accommodates the LECs' ability to complete
the meet point interconnections as soon as possible, with either
electrical or fiber transmission media. Moreover, ELI has the
ability to support all types of signaling commonly used between
LECs. This includes traditional inbound signaling (analog or
digital) and digital out-of-band signaling with SS7 signaling
protocol.
To ensure network reliability and system compatibility with
LEC embedded facilities and equipment, ELI has provisioned its
network with equipment documented by the RBOCs as acceptable for
purchase and installation within RBOC central offices and/or
facilities.
ELI continues to adhere to and review standards and
interconnection issues. In addition, ELI has established the same
physical, electrical, and protocol levels with USWC and other
independent LECs that will be required for intraexchange switched
telecommunications products and services the company proposes to
provide in Oregon. ELI's existing and proposed plant of system in
Oregon will not conflict with or adversely affect the operations
of any existing certified utility in the state that supplies the
same products or services to the public.
ELI seeks to provide universal access to its network, whether
by other service providers, subscribers, or competitors. In order
to accomplish this goal, ELI's fiber optic transmission network
and switching systems are designed to provide an open network
platform, allowing for maximum present flexibility and the
ability to grow as technology changes. ELI currently makes
physical collocation and interconnection available at its network
hubs to carriers, customers, and competitors.
ELI agrees to participate in all existing Commission approved
programs and can satisfy statutory requirements relating to the
provision of 911/E-911 services and the Telecommunications
Devices Access Program.
ELI will not provide operator services under contract with a
call aggregator as defined in ORS 759.690. ELI will not directly
provide operator services in Oregon but will contractually
arrange to have such services provided by an incumbent LEC or by
another company that is in compliance with all Commission rules.
CP 14: MFS INTELENET OF OREGON, INC.
On December 14, 1995, MFS Intelenet of Oregon, Inc. (MFS),
filed an application with the Commission for certification to
provide telecommunications service in Oregon as a competitive
provider. MFS's application seeks authority to provide
intraexchange switched services. MFS has been authorized to
provide interexchange telecommunications services on a resale and
a facilities basis. Docket UM 668, Order No. 94-1322.
MFS intends initially to offer services targeted to the
business customer market, especially small and mid-sized
businesses within its service territory. MFS will offer
intraexchange access services (basic business lines, key system
lines, analog private branch exchange [PBX] trunks, analog direct
inward dial [DID] trunks, digital PBX and DID trunks,
Centrex-type system lines); intraexchange usage services (direct
dial calling, toll-free calling [i.e., local 800, 950, or
comparable services), operator assisted calling, directory
assistance service, emergency 911 service at no charge to the
caller, and switched carrier access services, including
terminating access (to enable other common carriers to terminate
traffic via end user access services provided by MFS) and
originating access (to enable customers of MFS' intraexchange
access service to employ those services to access the intrastate,
interstate, and international calling service of other
interexchange carriers on an equal access (1+ or 10XXX) basis.
MFS may provide other intraexchange services in the future.
MFS also seeks authority to provide all intrastate intraexchange
services incidental, supplementary, or related to any of the
foregoing services.
MFS has applied for authority to provide telecommunications
service areas coextensive with the following local exchange
areas: Burlington, Lake Oswego, North Plains, Oak
Grove-Milwaukie, Oregon City, and Portland (USWC exchanges); and
Beaverton, Forest Grove, Gresham, Hillsboro, Scholls, Sherwood,
Stafford, and Tigard (GTE exchanges).
MFS intends to provide its services through an Ericcson AXE-10
switch. MFS's sister company, Metropolitan Fiber Systems of
Oregon, Inc. (MFS), is currently constructing a digital fiber
optic ring network in the Portland metropolitan area, pursuant to
authority granted in Order No. 94-1322. MFS will provide its
intraexchange services primarily using its own switch and
facilities leased from its sister company.
MFS Intelenet, Inc., the parent company of MFS, establishes
operating subsidiaries on a state-by-state basis. The switching
and network systems of the MFS Intelenet, Inc. corporate family
feature advanced common channel signaling (called CCS or SS7) and
database capabilities. It has established a matched pair of
service transfer point/service control point (STP/SCP) facilities
to enable CCS signaling between MFS affiliates and other carriers
for advanced call setup and CLASS features interoperability.
MFS Intelenet has also set up a Network Operations Control
Center (NOCC) in New Jersey, which is staffed 24 hours a day, 365
days per year. The NOCC monitors the operations of the switch,
all peripherals, and all network facilities on a continuous
basis. The NOCC is designed to allow MFS Intelenet technicians,
working in cooperation with MFS technicians, to detect troubles
as they occur and to implement corrective measure before
customers experience outages or service degradation.
MFS seeks to establish meet points and interconnect with ILEC
networks at various points, including ILEC end office switches,
EAS tandems, intraLATA toll tandems, IXC access tandems, and
operator services tandems. It will also request transport
facilities from ILECs to transport MFS services to remote
locations. Transport facilities will include both analog and
digital transmission media. The traffic will be handed to ILECs
at respective meet points and will be terminated at either the
customer premises, other carrier locations, or other MFS-ILEC
meet points. MFS will also request certain ancillary services
from ILECs, including 911 routing, directory assistance, number
portability, CLASS services, and operator services.
MFS will need to make co-carrier arrangements with the ILECs
covering number assignments; meet-point billing; reciprocal
traffic exchange and compensation; shared platforms for 911,
telecom relay, directory assistance, etc.; unbundled local loops;
and co-carrier number forwarding.
Functionally equivalent or substitute intraexchange switched
services are readily available in the MFS service territory from
incumbent carriers including USWC and GTE. In addition,
substitute or alternative services are also available from
Centrex resellers such as Enhanced Telemanagement, Inc., and
shared tenant service providers. Finally, if ELI's application is
granted, ELI will also provide functionally equivalent or
substitute intraexchange switched services.
CP 15: MCI METRO ACCESS TRANSMISSION SERVICES, INC.
On December 20, 1994, MCI Metro Access Transmission Services,
Inc. (MCImetro) applied for authority to provide
telecommunications service in Oregon as a competitive provider.
MCImetro is a wholly owned subsidiary of MCI Telecommunications
Corporation (MCIT). MCIT is certified in Oregon as a competitive
telecommunications provider. It provides interLATA and intraLATA
toll services, 800 services, and WAT services.
MCImetro intends to provide local exchange service and carrier
access services to business customers. These services will
include, but are not limited to, two-way local lines or trunks,
direct inward or outward dialing options, local calling operator
assistance services, directory assistance, dual party relay
service, and 911 emergency services via the established 911
network.
MCImetro seeks to provide services in the Portland
metropolitan area, including portions of Multnomah, Clackamas,
and Washington counties. Service will be provided in areas
coextensive with the following local exchange areas: Lake Oswego,
Milwaukie, Oak Grove, Oregon City, Portland (USWC exchanges);
Beaverton, Forest Grove, Gresham, Hillsboro, Scholls, Sherwood,
and Stafford (GTE exchanges).
MCImetro intends to own and deploy its own digital switches
with stored program control software. MCImetro has not yet
selected the switches it will deploy in Oregon.
If MCImetro can purchase transmission service from the
incumbent LECs in a cost effective manner, MCImetro will try to
do so. MCImetro anticipates that transmission service elements
such as loops and network access facilities will be available
from the LECs on an unbundled basis and at cost based rates in
the near future, as a result of UM 351.
If MCImetro cannot purchase cost-effective transmission
service from the incumbent LECs, MCImetro will construct its own
transmission facilities. In other jurisdictions where MCImetro
has constructed a redundant network, MCImetro has used high
reliability fiber rings with SONET technology for most of its
facilities. Attachment D to MCImetro's application describes its
network plan for Washington state, which has been approved by the
Washington Utility & Transportation Commission. If MCImetro
receives authority to operate in Oregon, it anticipates that its
network plan for Oregon would be similar.
APPEARANCES AT HEARING
The following parties entered appearances at the hearing in
these cases:
Party Representative
Electric Lightwave, Inc. (ELI) Ellen Deutsch
MFS Intelenet of Oregon, Inc. (MFS) Robert Berger and Leslie
Bottomly
MCI Metro Access Transmission
Services, Inc. (MCImetro) Beth Kaye and Susan Weiske
GTE Northwest, Inc. (GTE) Richard Potter
US West Communications, Inc. (USWC) Molly Hastings and Douglas
Owens
AT&T Communications of the
Pacific Northwest, Inc. (AT&T) Susan Proctor
Oregon Cable Telecommunications
Association (OCTA) Sara Siegler Miller
Oregon Exchange Carriers
Association (OECA) Robert Hollis
Oregon Independent Telephone
Association (OITA) Michael Morgan and Gary Bauer
Sprint Communications
Company L.P. (Sprint) Lesla Lehtonen
Teleport Communications
Group Inc. (TCG) Teresa Marrero and Mark Trinchero
Commission Staff (Staff) W. Benny Won
ORDER NO.
ADSRC Average Direct and Shared Residual Cost
AEC Alternative Exchange Carrier
ALI Automatic Location Identification
ASIC Average Service Incremental Cost (ADSRC minus Shared Residual Cost)
BOC Bell Operating Company, e.g., USWC
CCF Co-carrier Call Forwarding
CCL Carrier Common Line
CLASS Custom Local Area Signaling Services
cpm cents per minute
COLR Carrier of Last Resort
DNRI Directory Number Route Indexing
DS1 A type of high-speed private line service, transmitting at 1.544 megabytes per second, the equivalent capacity required to provide 24 voice grade equivalent channels
DS3 Another high-speed private line service, transmitting at 44.736 megabytes per second, the equivalent capacity required to provide 672 voice paths or 28 DS1s
DSS Digital Switched Services
EAS Extended Area Service
ESN Emergency Service Number
ILEC Independent Local Exchange Carrier
ISDN Integrated Services Digital Network
I-USC Interim Universal Service Charge
IXC Interexchange Carrier
LEC Local Exchange Company
LTR Local Transport Restructure
NAC Network Access Channel
NPA (Telephone) Numbering Plan Area codes
NXX Geographic number prefixes assigned to carriers
OCAF Oregon Customer Access Fund
OCAP Oregon Customer Access Plan
OUSF Oregon Universal Service Fund
PBX Private Branch Exchange
PIU Percentage of Interstate Usage
PLU Percentage of Local Usage
PSAP Public Safety Answering Point
RCC Radio Common Carrier
RCF Remote Call Forwarding
SS7 Signalling System Seven
STS Shared Telecommunications Service
TSLRIC Total Service Long Run Incremental Cost (sum of service
specific volume sensitive costs plus the service specific volume
insensitive costs)